EXECUTIVE
SUMMARY
The subject of capital budgeting--or indeed public
budgeting
for any purpose--may appear to be of interest to only a special
audience: government professionals "inside the Beltway" and perhaps some analysts
in the investment community. Nothing could be further from the
truth.
The budget of any organization, private or public, is a
statement of both the resources to be made available to
the organization and the priorities of those who manage
it. The budget that the President submits to the Congress, which
in fiscal year 1999 covered expenditures of nearly $2 trillion,
tells the American people how the administration proposes to
spend their taxes and, until recently, the proceeds of federal
debt issued to finance the shortfall between total expenditures
and revenues. The budget is thus inherently a political document,
but in the best sense of the term. This is because it reflects
the collective judgment of the individuals in a democracy about
how much public funds are to be raised and how they are to be
used.
This commission has devoted its attention to one
particular
kind of expenditure in the federal budget: spending on "capital." Although this term has been
defined in various ways for different purposes, a common element
among all of the definitions is that capital spending--whether
undertaken by the private or public sector--is intended to
generate benefits over the long run.
In this report, we have concentrated on capital spending
by
the federal government because it is our charge. But we cannot
emphasize too strongly that capital spending at all levels of
government, as well as by the private sector, provides important
benefits to the nation as a whole in significant part because
those benefits are delivered over the long run. It is
easy in the day-to-day battles over budget policy to forget that
such spending helps determine the kind of society that we and our
children will live in--not just this year but many years from now
as well. We therefore encourage this president and future
presidents to help educate American citizens about the importance
of devoting current resources toward future needs--in the form of
spending on capital by both the private and public sectors.
Most firms in the private sector, as well as many state
and
local governments, recognize the importance of capital
expenditures by making decisions about them separately from
decisions about how much to spend on annual operating expenses.
By contrast, the federal government has never done this.
This commission has been directed to examine whether
this
practice ought to be changed--that is, whether the federal
government should adopt a "capital budget"--and, if not,
what other steps, if any, should be taken to improve the federal
decision-making process as it relates to spending on capital or "investment" expenditures.
Capital budgeting is a process that takes explicit
account of
capital spending levels. In this report, we primarily examine
versions of a capital budget in which either: (1) the size of the
deficit or surplus is made to depend, in part or in whole, on the
amount of expenditures defined as "capital," or (2) a single decision is
made about how much to spend on "capital," under some definition. A
variation of the first definition is what we label the "simplistic" version of the capital
budget, one in which capital spending may be financed, in part or
in total, by borrowing. We treat the second definition as the
equivalent of imposing a separate "cap" on expenditures defined to
be capital, or in the alternative, a process whereby the
depreciation of capital is explicitly taken into account in the
budget process. We briefly note in a concluding section that
there are other, perhaps less formal, variations of a capital
budget that we do not extensively analyze here.
The commission had its origins during the
Congressional debate
about whether to amend the Constitution to require the federal
government to have a balanced budget every year. Nothing in this
report should be construed as support for the balanced budget
amendment considered by the Senate in 1996.
(a)
Nor does the commission endorse the adoption of the simplistic
version of the capital budget. Furthermore, a majority of the
members of the commission does not support, at this time,
adopting a budget procedure that would impose a separate cap on
capital spending.(b) The reasons
for reaching these conclusions are spelled out in the body of the
report.
At the same time, we have concluded from our study of
existing
practices and after gathering evidence from a wide range of
experts, that the existing federal budget process--as it affects
decision-making about capital expenditures as well as other types
of spending--has significant weaknesses. Insufficient attention
is paid to the long-run consequences of budget
decisions. Capital spending in particular is inefficiently
allocated among projects. Moreover, the current process
shortchanges the maintenance of existing assets.
(c)
Accordingly, the commission urges the Congress
and the executive branch to undertake a thorough examination of
how the budget process may be improved beyond addressing
capital-related needs. Toward this end, it may be productive for
both branches to create a new Commission on Budget Concepts to
aid them with this task.
(d)
In the meantime, we believe there are a series of
constructive
responses to the shortcomings we have identified, though they do
not include adopting any particular form of a capital budget as
we have just defined the term. These responses are aimed at
improving each of the component parts of the budget process: setting
priorities currently and for the long run, making budget
decisions in the current year, reporting on those
decisions, and subsequently evaluating them in order
to make improvements in future years. Key to achieving these
improvements is ensuring that the appropriate information
is made available to decision-makers and the public throughout
the process so that policy makers (1) are properly informed when
deciding how to spend taxpayers' money and (2) can be held
accountable by the public for those decisions.
The recommendations we summarize below take
account of two
important features of federal budgeting.
First, many government efforts have objectives, such as
the
management of foreign affairs or the defense of the nation, that
cannot be readily measured in monetary terms. In stark contrast,
it is relatively easy to keep score in the private sector, where
firms are often judged by a single metric, such as current
profitability, return on equity, or the dollar value of their
shareholders' equity.
Second, borrowing is subject to less discipline at the
federal
level than it is at lower levels of government. States and
localities cannot "print money" to cover the
debts they issue, whereas one arm of the federal government--the
Federal Reserve--has the ability to "monetize" debt issued by the
Treasury. A related difference is that federal debt is viewed by
the marketplace as practically free of default risk, whereas
states and localities have a strong interest in maintaining high
credit ratings, which constrains borrowing at the state and local
level.(e)
These considerations necessarily imply that
federal budgeting rules should not simply replicate rules that
may be used in the private sector or at the state and local
levels of government. But at the same time, because the existing
federal budget process has the weaknesses we have noted, certain
improvements are appropriate. We have concentrated on suggestions
for the executive branch; however, as will become evident below,
certain of these require the cooperation of and concurrence by
the Congress.
We also recognize the essential role of the
American people as monitors, advocates, and parties whose
interests ultimately are at stake during the budget process. For
this reason it is important to increase the transparency of that
process--not only to enhance the quality of inputs to the
Congress from the private sector and other levels of government,
but also to increase the federal government's accountability to
the American people.
To facilitate the setting of priorities
among all programs, not just those involving capital
expenditures, the commission recommends:
Recommendation 1: Five-Year
Strategic Plans.--Although federal agencies are now
required (under the Government Performance and Results Act) to
prepare strategic plans every three years and performance plans
annually, this process should be improved in several respects:
- The strategic plans should (1) be
prepared annually, (2) be integrated with the annual
performance plans and the agencies' five-year budget
projections that are now submitted to the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB), and (3) be included as an
integral part of the budget justifications sent to the
Congress.
- The strategic plans of the agencies
and their annual budgets should be tied to the
life-cycles of their capital assets.
- OMB should standardize the formats
of these plans, in consultation with GAO and CBO, to make
them more useful to policy makers.
- OMB should expand its efforts to
evaluate the plans and facilitate the Administration's
use of them for government-wide planning.
- Congress should take such plans into
account in deciding on annual agency appropriations. It
should also consider how it might improve its own
procedures so that it can pay more attention both to the
longer-run implications of its current year decisions and
to issues with longer-run consequences. In undertaking
this task, Congress might find it useful to take
advantage of the wide range of institutional expertise
available to it, including resources within the
Congressional Budget Office, the General Accounting
Office, and the Congressional Research Service.
Recommendation 2: Benefit-Cost
Assessments.--There should be an ongoing effort
within the federal government to analyze the benefits and costs
of all major government programs (whether or not related to
capital spending), so that they can be adjusted, refashioned, or
eliminated, as appropriate. OMB, the agencies, and the Congress
(through GAO and CBO in particular) should be given the resources
to carry out this important function.
To improve the process by which annual
budget decisions are made, the commission recommends:
Recommendation 3: Capital
Acquisition Funds.--To promote better planning and
budgeting of capital expenditures for federally owned facilities,
Congress and the executive branch should experiment by adopting
for one or more agencies separate appropriations for "capital acquisition funds" (CAFs).
Budget authority would be lodged in the CAFs for federally owned
capital assets. The CAFs would "rent out"
their facilities to the various programs within each agency,
charging them the equivalent of debt service.
- CAFs would help ensure that
individual programs are assessed the cost of using
capital assets.
- By spreading capital costs across
entire agencies, CAFs would help smooth out the lumpiness
in appropriations sometimes associated with large capital
projects.
- If the CAF experiment proves
successful, the CAF approach should be adopted throughout
the government.
Recommendation 4: Full Funding for
Capital Projects.--All capital projects, or usable
segments thereof, should be fully funded before the work begins.
In this way, Congress can fully evaluate their likely costs and
benefits before appropriating funds for them.
Recommendation 5: Adhering to the
Scoring Rules for Leasing.--Existing rules that
govern the scoring of leases should be strictly followed by both
agencies and the Congress. This will discourage the signing of
short-term leases when it is cheaper over the long run to
construct or purchase a facility.(f)
Recommendation 6: Trust Fund
Reforms.--Although trust funds for highways,
airports, and other uses insulate certain types of spending from
the balancing process that is inherent in the rest of the budget,
they can be useful if the funds going into them truly represent
charges or fees for the use of the government services they
support. But this purpose is fulfilled only if the monies raised
by earmarked taxes or fees to support infrastructure or other
types of capital--averaged over some reasonable period, such as
three years--are actually spent on the dedicated uses.
- To ensure that this is done, the
President's budget should disclose the earmarked taxes or
fees and spending of these various capital-related trust
funds. This will allow policy makers to make informed
decisions about whether to increase spending on the
authorized activities or reduce the charges now being
assessed purportedly to finance those activities.
- State and local governments that are
recipients of capital-related grants from the federal
government should be required to maintain their
capital--such as highways--as a condition to receiving
any additional federal aid (unless those governments can
demonstrate that there is no longer a need for the assets
the federal government initially supported).
Recommendation 7: Incentives for
Asset Management.--The executive branch and the
Congress should experiment with incentives to encourage agencies
to manage their assets efficiently. One possibility might be to
allow, on an experimental basis, one or more agencies to keep a
limited portion of the revenues they raise from selling or
renting out existing assets.
Steps must be taken to improve the
methods that are used to give the results of those decisions (and
the programs they support) to the public and policy makers. In
particular:
Recommendation 8: Clarification of
the Federal Budget Presentation.--The President's
annual budget should contain a breakdown of proposed current and
projected federal spending over the budget year and the
subsequent four years among the following categories: investment,
operating expenditures, transfers to individuals, and interest.
Such a breakdown would make available to policy makers and the
wider public the President's long-run vision for federal
spending. This information might also encourage Congress to find
ways of taking a longer-run view in its annual budget
deliberations.(g)
Recommendation 9: Financial
Statement Reporting.--Reporting on financial
activities and asset positions of the federal government should
be enhanced in a number of ways to better inform the Congress and
the public about the ways in which the federal government's
assets are being used and maintained:
- Federal agencies should be required
to issue to policy makers and the public more detailed
information (both in print form and on their websites)
about the composition and condition of the federally
owned or managed capital assets under their control. OMB
should consolidate these reports, which should continue
to be based on independently developed accounting
standards, and report on them in summary fashion in the
annual budget.
- There should be enough information
in the consolidated reports to provide Congress and the
public with accurate benchmarks for making appropriate
comparisons both in the current year and over time.
- The calculation of depreciation in
various government reports should be standardized.
With more comprehensive, objective information
on how the federal government as a whole, as well as individual
agencies and programs, have used resources, increased or depleted
assets, and undertaken new investments, debates over critical
national policies would be better informed. Private corporations
report audited financial results and asset and liability
positions to investors. By the same token, the federal government
should make available to the American people audited financial
statements and underlying detail that go well beyond the
information shown annually in the unified budget. Just as
corporate decision-makers have accurate accounting data to help
them assess past performance and make decisions about the future,
Congress and the public should also have accurate accounting on
federal assets and investments.
Recommendation 10: Condition of
Existing Assets.--Work is planned at the federal
level for agencies to begin developing standardized methods for
estimating deferred maintenance. The commission strongly supports
these efforts and encourages OMB to work with the agencies to
complete this task promptly and to implement its results. In
addition, the federal government, working with states and
localities, should endeavor to report on the condition of assets
owned at these lower levels of government, or at least those that
have received federal support. In combination with the rest of
the information provided in the audited financial statements,
data on deferred maintenance will enable policy makers to develop
sound plans for maintaining existing assets and spending on new
ones where that is advisable.
Finally, steps should be taken to
improve the process used in evaluating the impact of past
budgetary decisions, so that policy makers can be in a position
to make improvements, if warranted.
Recommendation 11: Federal "Report
Card."--Under OMB guidance, agencies should assess the extent to which major
investment projects have produced returns in excess of some
benchmark cost of capital, such as the prevailing interest rate
on long-term federal debt, the average cost of capital expected
by private market investors, or some other threshold that OMB
believes the public would find useful. This federal "Report
Card" could be included in the President's annual budget. The
commission recognizes that the projects for which it might be
feasible to provide a monetary analysis may account for a
relatively small fraction of total spending; nonetheless, it
believes that over time advances in estimating techniques may
permit a larger fraction of total spending to be evaluated in
this manner. Where benefits and costs cannot be expressed in
monetary terms, the evaluations should identify project
objectives and assess outcomes qualitatively.
The foregoing recommendations are summarized in
the table on the following page. The columns in the table refer
to three different classes of capital, which are discussed in the
body of the report: the federal government's own assets (such as
buildings in which federal agencies are located), the federal
government's investment in assets owned by state and local
governments (such as highways), and the federal government's
investment in what we have labeled intangible national assets
that are financed but not owned by the government (such as
benefits accruing from federal expenditures on research and
development and or on education). Our recommendations are then
classified both by the stage of the budget process at which they
are directed and by the types of capital that they are likely to
affect. Because a number of our recommendations are designed to
improve decision-making with respect to one or more categories of
capital, they are listed in multiple columns.
While the primary responsibility for initiating
most of the foregoing recommendations rests with the executive
branch, in certain cases Congress also has an important role.
Indeed, virtually all of the recommendations require active
Congressional cooperation if they are to have a positive effect
on the budget process and budget decisions.
Although the commission as a whole does not
endorse setting a separate cap on capital spending, it
nonetheless discussed the technical details of such a change in
budget procedure. The concluding section of this report contains
our findings on these issues, outlines the key pros and cons of
subjecting capital spending to its own limit, analyzes proposals
to reflect depreciation of capital assets in the budget process,
and briefly describes some alternative versions of a capital
budget.
In sum, the federal budget process can be and
should be improved. The commission believes the recommendations
outlined in this report would help accomplish this objective.
WHAT IS
"CAPITAL"?
This commission has been charged with examining
capital budgeting in other countries, states and local
governments, and the private sector, and, in the process, with
addressing a number of questions about capital budgeting. It is
only appropriate, therefore, to begin with the threshold issue:
what is "capital" (or its annualized counterpart, "investment")?
The commission has not settled on, nor does it
endorse, a single definition of capital.(1) Instead, a
series of distinctions between different types of capital or "investment"
spending, both by governments and by firms in the private sector,
seem warranted for different purposes (and different
commissioners place varying amounts of emphasis on alternative
definitions of capital).
One distinction relates to the functions
of capital. At its broadest level, any spending that yields
benefits beyond the typical reporting period (such as a year)
should be considered to be investment, and "capital"
refers to the assets created by this spending. Such a definition
would encompass spending not only on physical or fixed assets,
such as structures and equipment, but also on human and a variety
of intangible assets. "Human capital"
consists of the skills imparted to individuals through training
and education that enable them to increase their earnings not
just in a single year, but potentially throughout their lives.
Intangible assets can cover a very broad class of items. In
private sector financial accounting, for example, intangibles are
often measured by the expenditures required to gain patents,
copyrights, trademarks, or other intellectual property
protection. Certain types of public spending--including research
and development (R&D), defense, nutrition, disease
prevention, police protection, and drug treatment and prevention
programs--may also produce intangible assets that deliver, or are
at least designed to deliver, benefits over years, if not
lifetimes.
Broad definitions of investment or capital
could be useful for several purposes. For example, to the extent
citizens and policy makers are interested in enhancing economic
growth, the definition should count both private and public
sector spending on buildings, equipment, research and development
(including some defense-related R&D), and education and
training. An even broader definition would be justified if the
goal were to measure capital aimed at improving social
welfare--one that included expenditures on national defense and
police to enhance security as well as spending on childhood
immunization, maternal health, nutrition, and substance abuse, to
improve the health and well-being of citizens over many years.
(h)
The accounting standards used in the private
sector do not take such an expansive approach to the definition
of capital. Generally speaking, they limit capital to physical
and certain intangible assets (such as investments in
intellectual property). Similarly, the National Income and
Product Accounts (NIPA)--the federal government's statistical
system for collecting and reporting data on overall economic
activity--define capital to be spending only on physical assets.(2) It is important to keep in mind, however, that
while these accounting standards may be conservative, they do not
necessarily constrain the way managers think about spending that
provides longer-run benefits. For example, although private
sector accounting standards define employee training expenditures
as an expense, this spending typically generates longer-term
benefits to the firm (and to the employees). The fact that these
expenditures are written off during the course of a year does not
stop managers or investors from considering them as investments
in the future well-being of the firm.
A second distinction relates to who owns
capital:
specifically, whether it is owned privately or publicly (and if
publicly, by federal, state, or local governments). Individuals
and firms reap most of the benefits from the spending on capital
they undertake; however, the public benefits when government is
making the expenditures. For example, government spending to
educate each generation of citizens benefits the entire public by
ensuring that the population continues to be literate, cognizant
of the benefits of our system of government, and able to work in
an ever-changing economic environment. Similarly, when the
government spends money on the nation's defense or finances basic
scientific research, the benefits accrue to all citizens.
Appropriately enough, economists call investments that confer
benefits on a wide class of parties "public goods,"
because no private person or firm can capture all of their
benefits. Identifying and funding those programs that produce
returns to society well above the cost of capital is especially
important for enhancing economic growth.
These points highlight the different criteria
that are used to decide whether to add to private and public
capital. In the private sector, capital spending decisions are
made based primarily on how they affect shareholders, and are
evaluated predominantly in monetary terms. In the public sector,
decisions about capital take into account the impact on the
public at large and rest on both monetary and non-monetary
considerations.
A third distinction is between federal
government capital and national capital. Federal
government capital, as we use the term, refers only to those
assets the government owns, such as federal buildings or federal
military hardware. National capital is a broader term, including
all government spending aimed at delivering long-term benefits to
any portion of the nation, whether or not it is owned by the
federal government. So, for example, using the broad functional
definition of capital discussed above, national capital would
include spending at all levels of government on roads and other
physical assets, research and development, and education and
training, among other items. At the federal level, what OMB
labels as "federal investment outlays," illustrated
in Table 1, represents federally financed national capital
regardless of who owns it.(3)
As the table shows, nearly half of the federal
government's investment outlays in fiscal year 1997 were devoted
to physical capital, about one-third to research and development,
and the balance to education and training--roughly the same
proportions that were prevalent during the earlier part of the
decade.(4)
Federal government capital, in contrast, can be
defined as including only assets owned by the federal government,
so it can be accounted for in a fashion similar to the way
capital is measured in the private sector. For example, OMB's Capital
Programming Guide, which provides guidance to federal
agencies on capital planning, procurement, and management,
defines "federal capital" to include
land, structures, equipment, and intellectual property (including
software) belonging to the federal government that has an
estimated useful life of at least two years. Consistent with this
definition, Table 2 illustrates how the federal government
provided almost $66 billion of budget authority for fiscal year
1997 on "major capital acquisitions": government
buildings, information technology, and "other items"
(weapons systems in the case of the Department of Defense, and
facilities and equipment for other agencies). The table shows
that the major part of the federally owned investment was for
defense-related purposes.
This distinction between "national" and
"government" capital is of more than academic interest. As discussed below, the
government of New Zealand has adopted a separate capital budget
but only for government capital. In contrast, the General
Accounting Office has suggested defining a budget target that is
a variation of national capital: public investments that promise "to
raise the private sector's long-run productivity,"
which would include spending on infrastructure, non-defense
R&D, education and training, and some defense activities, but
would specifically exclude what GAO calls "federal capital," such as government-owned
buildings, weapon systems, and
land [GAO, 1993].
A fourth definitional distinction is between
capital created by (1) direct government spending and (2) public
and private capital spending induced by government policies. The
advantage of confining any definition to direct spending is that
measurement is relatively easy. Nonetheless, if the objective is
to measure the impact of overall government policy on national
capital (narrowly or broadly defined), then a definition based
only on the government's direct expenditures is too limited. A
full accounting would also require inclusion of capital spending
at the state and local levels and by the private sector that may
be brought about by such policies as federal deficit reduction
(through lower interest rates), and targeted tax incentives, as
well as regulatory mandates such as those requiring or inducing
expenditures on pollution control or occupational safety.(5) Granted, such induced spending may be very
important;
however, the operational problem with adding induced expenditures
is that they cannot be directly measured, but instead must be
estimated, using economic models or survey responses.
The different definitions underscore the
proposition that "capital" is
not a single, uniform concept, but one that varies according to
why the term is being used. Indeed, this is one reason that most
members of the commission are opposed to recommending that a
separate capital budget using one single definition of capital be
adopted for decision-making purposes. Nonetheless, definitional
issues should not stand in the way of illuminating the
consequences of choosing among different government programs,
whether or not they are labeled as capital. Nor should debate
over definitions distract attention from (1) the need to improve
planning and evaluation for whatever expenditures policy makers
may choose to label as capital, or, (2) in the case of federal
capital in particular, the need to identify the assets the
government has and report them in a coherent way.
Finally, one important characteristic of much
(but not all) capital spending is that its value declines over
time. Buildings and machines wear out. Patents and copyrights
have limited lives. Even the value of basic education and
training may decline in a world of continuing technological
change, which requires many workers to upgrade their skills
constantly to maintain their earnings.
Accounting standards in the private sector, as
well as the concepts reflected in the National Income and Product
Accounts, take account of the declining value of capital items by
requiring property and plant and equipment (but not land) to be "depreciated" or
"amortized" over their "useful lives." The annual
amounts of depreciation or amortization represent expenses that,
along with salaries, supplies, rent, taxes, and other expense
items, are deducted from annual revenue to determine profits each
year.(6)
A number of different methods for depreciation and
amortization are in use, ranging from the "straight-line"
method (that computes the annual deduction simply by dividing the
original capital investment by the years of useful life) to
various forms of "accelerated depreciation" (that deduct
more in the early years of an asset's
useful life and less in later years). Businesses may also use
depreciation methods for financial accounting purposes that are
different from those they use to compute their income tax
liability.
Some state and local governments account for
the declining value of their debt-financed capital assets by
including in their annual budgets the annual debt service on the
bonds they issued to finance the investments. Debt service
includes interest and the annual amount of the principal of the
bond that is paid off (similar to amortization of principal on a
mortgage that individuals may take out to finance their homes) or
put into a "sinking fund" that is
eventually used to pay off the bonds when they mature. The
amortization component of the debt service charge is analogous to
depreciation, but with a time profile that is the opposite of
accelerated depreciation--much larger deductions in the later
years than in the earlier years.
BUDGETING
CAPITAL
The executive order directs the commission to
report specifically on capital budgeting practices used in the
private sector, by state and local governments and in other
countries, and then to explain the relevance of those practices
for budget decisions made by the federal government.
By definition, a budget is a constraint because
it implies the existence of a finite amount of resources that can
be allocated among alternative uses. But what is it that limits
the amount of available money? The vastly different answers to
this question for private firms, state and local governments, and
the federal government help shed light on the extent to which
capital budgeting practices followed elsewhere are suitable for
the federal budget.
Capital Budgeting in the Private
Sector
The American economy is populated by over
twenty million businesses, large and small, which surely have
different ways of budgeting capital expenditures. Nonetheless,
certain conventions have become standardized through custom and
repetition, as well as through formal professional practice. As a
result, it is possible to describe a stylized process that many
firms, typically larger publicly held corporations, use to
analyze their capital spending options, to choose among them, and
then to account for those choices. To help understand these
conventions, it is useful to refer to three basic financial
statements that are found in the annual reports of publicly held
companies: the balance sheet, the income statement, and the
statement of cash flows.
The balance sheet provides a financial
snapshot at a single point in time, usually at the end of a
reporting year, of the firm's assets (on one side) and
liabilities and net worth (on the other). The two sides add to
the same total. Assets are "financed," as
it were, by borrowing (liabilities) and shareholders'
contributions (paid-in capital and retained earnings). Broadly
speaking, three categories of assets are reported on the balance
sheet: short-term assets (such as cash, marketable securities,
receivables, and inventories), fixed assets (structures and
equipment) minus any cumulative depreciation, and intangible
assets minus any cumulative amortization. Using the nomenclature
of this report, capital for private firms consists of fixed
assets and, under some definitions, intangible assets as well.(11) It is worth noting that private sector accounting
has
been standardized in Generally Accepted Accounting Principles
(GAAP), which are used to prepare financial statements.(12) The Financial Accounting Standards Board, an
independent body of experts, is responsible for seeing that the
principles embodied in GAAP are maintained, updated, and applied
in a fair and reasonable manner.(13)
The income statement is an accounting
of revenues and expenses over a certain time frame, typically a
year, with the difference representing the firm's profit or loss.
Because businesses exist to generate profits, spending decisions
by private companies--including whether and how much to invest in
capital projects--are judged predominantly by their likely impact
on profitability. Investments in capital projects by definition
are designed to deliver benefits over the long run, so capital
spending does not appear on the income statement. Instead, the
depreciation or amortization of existing capital recorded on the
balance sheet shows up on the income statement as an expense that
reduces reported profits.
Where, then, might spending on capital show up?
The typical place is on the statement of cash flows.
This statement combines information on where a firm gets its
money and where it spends it during the course of a year: on
operating activities, interest on any outstanding debt, and the
full cost of capital projects.
How do firms decide how much capital spending
to undertake, and of their many possible options, which projects
to pursue? Here, again, practices surely vary. But certain facts
and conventions are widely understood.
First, most firms cannot spend without limits:
they are constrained by their cash on hand, revenue likely to be
realized in the short run, and how much additional cash they
might be able to raise by selling existing assets, borrowing, or
selling new equity.(14) In turn,
creditors
and investors decide whether to
provide funds, if they are requested, and on what terms based on
the firm's ability to repay its debts (in the case of borrowings)
and generate profits (in the case of equity sales). In short,
firms in the private sector are subject to market discipline.
Second, it is standard practice in private
industry for firms to assess their capital projects by estimating
their "net present value." Net present
value (NPV) is calculated by projecting the future cash flows the
investment is likely to generate (such as rentals from a building
or cost savings from invesing in new equipment or machinery), "discounting" the
future cash flows by the "time value of money," taking appropriate
account of the risk of investment,
and then subtracting the initial cost of the endeavor. Future
cash flows are discounted because a dollar today is worth more
than a dollar to be received in two, three, or several years
hence (since the dollar today can be invested in a financial
instrument and earn a rate of interest).
According to standard practice, it makes
economic sense to undertake a capital project only if its NPV is
positive (the discounted returns are greater than the project's
cost), and even then a firm may decide not to proceed.(15) For example, if the discount rate is 10 percent, a
project costing $1 million but projected to generate net revenues
of $200,000 annually for ten years, would have a NPV of $229,000.
But if annual net revenues are projected to be only $100,000 over
the same time period, the project should not be pursued because
its NPV is a negative $386,000 (which doesn't even cover the
project's cost).
Passing the NPV test, however, does not mean
that a project will be authorized. A firm may have many potential
projects that look promising when judged by their NPVs; however,
it might not pursue all of them because it may have strategic
objectives that cannot be readily quantified which limit the
range of investments it can undertake. The firm may also be
reluctant for other reasons to seek outside financing (preferring
to undertake only those projects that can be financed with cash
on hand), or to limit its borrowing or sale of equity.
Third, regardless of which of these approaches
(or others) private firms may employ to decide how much capital
investment to undertake and which projects to pursue, all of them
ultimately measure the probable success of the projects by a
single metric--the likely effect on future financial performance.
Moreover, the process of evaluating these undertakings is
different from that of deciding whether to make certain
expenditures for operating purposes (the expenses necessary to
keep the business running on a day-to-day basis). These decisions
do not require long-run projections of impacts or discounting
into the future, although techniques such as calculating NPVs are
often used to decide whether to terminate existing lines of
activity. Accordingly, operating budgets are often prepared and
overseen in the private sector through a process that is separate
from the capital budget (although both processes are often linked
by an overall management plan).
(16)
Finally, a firm's decision to undertake one or
more capital projects is not necessarily linked with a decision
about how to finance those projects. Some firms, averse or unable
to take on additional debt, may finance all, most, or part of
their capital projects with cash on hand; others may borrow; and
still others may sell equity. But just because capital spending
may require a separate decision and budget, it need not be
financed to any degree with additional debt.
Capital Budgeting by State and Local
Governments
Just as there is no single capital budgeting
practice prevalent in the private sector, the approach to capital
budgets also varies among state and local governments.
Nonetheless, some general tendencies are worth noting.(17)
First, most state governments maintain a
capital budget separate from the operating budget. However,
states differ substantially in how they define capital, the
degree to which capital is separate in the governor's proposed
budget and in the legislature's budget, and the means by which
they finance capital expenditures.
(18)
Second, whether or not states budget capital
spending separately from other expenditures, most states have
long-range capital plans, ranging from three to ten years, with
five years being the most frequent planning horizon. The spending
figures in these plans tend not to be as detailed as the figures
included in the annual budgets.
Third, available survey evidence indicates that
the states most satisfied with their capital budgeting process
use some method of keeping their legislatures regularly informed
about capital needs. Some state legislatures also have a separate
committee charged with overseeing all or most capital projects
and their financing.
Fourth, unlike the private sector, where
different capital projects can be judged by the common standard
of impact on profitability, governments are responsible for a
variety of functions, including police protection, health care,
and education, whose benefits generally cannot be reduced to
dollars and cents. This is a common situation shared by all
levels of government. Nonetheless, governments must set
priorities in deciding how to spend tax revenues and any borrowed
funds.
How do state governments set priorities in
deciding on their capital expenditures? Although some do it
project-by-project, or case-by-case, most states have formal
mechanisms, either in statute or by practice, for setting
priorities. Many states that take this approach set priorities on
a functional basis, allocating expenditures for higher education,
transportation, aiding local governments, or protecting natural
resources. Others have statutes that give priorities to certain
activities, such as health and safety.
Fifth, contrary to popular belief, state
governments do not always finance their capital projects by
borrowing. To the contrary, states often dip into general
revenues to pay for capital items, although the extent to which
they are allowed or choose to do so varies. Other major sources
of revenue for state capital spending include excise taxes (such
as taxes on gasoline) or grants from the federal government. In
addition, while debt service--interest and repayment of
principal--typically shows up in state operating budgets, no
state budget includes charges for depreciation.(19) Many states impose user fees on intended
beneficiaries
of capital projects in order to help service the debt issued to
finance them.
Finally, most states have either constitutional
or statutory limits (often with referendum requirements) on the
amount of debt they may issue. State borrowing is also
disciplined by the market. Rating agencies determine the ratings
they give to a state's bonds, which strongly influence the
interest rate at which those bonds can be marketed. These ratings
are set in significant part by measuring the amount of state debt
outstanding against the economic output generated in the state.
Higher interest rates due to adverse ratings can force states to
limit their borrowing.
As a broad generalization, local governments
follow procedures and conventions similar to those outlined for
state governments.
Current Budgeting by the Federal
Government
It may be surprising to some that throughout
much of American history, the federal government had no central
budget. Until the Budget and Accounting Act of 1921, which
created the Bureau of the Budget, each individual agency
submitted a budget to Congress. Since 1921, the Bureau of the
Budget (now OMB) has coordinated the preparation and submission
of a Presidential budget for the entire executive branch. The
President is required to submit the budget for the coming fiscal
year by the first Monday in February. This gives Congress eight
months to enact the legislation that will continue the operation
of most government operations and programs. If the necessary
appropriations laws have not been enacted by October 1, temporary
"continuing resolutions" usually
provide funds until full-year appropriations are enacted.
Although the Congress considers the President's
budget proposals, it usually does not actually pass a law setting
forth a budget (although, as discussed below, the "budget resolution" passed by
Congress establishes a framework for later
Congressional consideration of different pieces of the budget).
Instead, it enacts thirteen separate appropriations bills for the
approximately one-third of all federal spending that is deemed to
be "discretionary." The thirteen
appropriations bills are developed for full Congressional
consideration by the same number of subcommittees of the
Appropriations Committees of each chamber.
The other two-thirds of the budget covers
so-called "mandatory spending," which is
mainly for entitlement programs such as Social Security,
Medicare, Medicaid, and unemployment insurance. Mandatory
spending continues at levels regulated by standing laws unless
Congress enacts legislation to change them (for example, by
changing a benefit formula). The same is true of tax receipts.
Congress assigns responsibility for legislation governing
mandatory spending and receipts to the authorizing (rather than
appropriations) committees.
Until the Congressional Budget Act of 1974,
Congress had no procedures for coordinating legislation governing
appropriations, mandatory spending, and revenues into an overall
fiscal policy. Instead, a fiscal policy simply emerged as the sum
of all of the enacted bills. The 1974 Act aimed at bringing more
order to the budget process by creating separate budget
committees in both the House and the Senate, and the
Congressional Budget Office (the congressional counterpart to
OMB), which provides information to Congress about the costs and
effects of legislation. In addition, the Act requires Congress
first to decide what the projected budget surplus or deficit
should be and then to be guided by that decision in enacting
spending and revenue bills.
More specifically, the 1974 Act calls for
Congress to adopt each year a "budget resolution" that sets a ceiling
on total outlays and a floor on
total receipts. The resolution, which is not presented to the
President because it is technically not a law, also allocates "budget authority" and "outlays," by
functional categories, to the appropriations committees (for
discretionary spending) and the authorizing committees (for
mandatory spending). The appropriations committees, in turn,
further allocate budget authority among their thirteen
subcommittees, which must report bills back to the full committee
consistent with those allocations. The resolution may also direct
authorizing committees to achieve a specified amount of savings
by reducing mandatory spending or increasing receipts. Finally,
the 1974 Act established parliamentary rules ("super-majority" voting requirements in the
Senate) to stop bills that violate the
budget resolution.
The distinction between "budget authority" and
"outlays" is fundamental to understanding the way budget decisions are
actually made. Congress grants budget authority (BA), enabling
agencies to incur obligations. Those obligations, in turn,
require outlays (actual cash payments). Capital expenditures and
operating expenses typically have very different "outlay
rates." Capital projects are often completed over several
years, so the outlays for them are spread out over some period of
time. In contrast, the outlays for such things as salaries of
government workers, repairs, and maintenance, along with payments
under the various entitlement programs, typically coincide with
the amount of BA for the same year.
The Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 added
further requirements to the budget process for fiscal years
1991-95. The BEA has been extended twice so that its
requirements now apply (with amendments) through fiscal year
2002:
- The BEA divided all discretionary
spending, of which capital spending is a part, into
categories and imposed statutory limits or "caps" on
each category (on both BA and outlays). The categories
change from year to year, but currently consist of
defense, non-defense, violent crime reduction, highways,
and mass transit. The separate caps for defense and
non-defense are replaced after fiscal year 1999 by a "discretionary spending"
category, while the other categories remain intact. The
violent crime reduction category expires after fiscal
year 2000, leaving the discretionary, highways, and mass
transit categories. Increases in taxes do not increase
spending allowed by the caps (although the BEA rules
allow discretionary spending to be offset by fees charged
for goods and services when the fees are authorized in
appropriations acts). The caps were intended to restrain
the growth of spending, whether or not additional tax
revenues for more spending could be found.
- The BEA contained "pay-as-you-go"
(PAYGO) provisions to ensure that the cumulative impact
of changes in legislation affecting mandatory spending or
receipts do not increase the deficit. In other words, any
increases in mandatory benefits must be financed either
by cuts in other mandatory spending or by increased
revenue. Because most capital expenditures are
discretionary, the PAYGO rules seldom apply to capital
spending.
The federal budget contains
several types of funds. The "general fund" is
the broadest and includes income and some excise tax receipts. It
also includes proceeds of general borrowing, on the revenue side
of the budget; on the expense side, it includes national defense,
interest on the federal debt, operating expenses of most federal
agencies, and some capital expenditures (broadly defined) on
R&D, education, and infrastructure and other physical capital
spending. "Special funds" are earmarked for specific purposes; while they are not designated by
law as "trust funds," they do not differ from them in substance.(20)
Most special funds are financed by user fees. "Trust funds" also have dedicated uses, and are
financed by user fees or taxes;
when their surpluses are borrowed, the funds receive interest. A
few of the best-known trust funds are those for Social Security,
Medicare, and highways (although there are about 150 such trust
funds in total).(21)
Although each of the trust funds is technically
distinct, they are reported on a combined basis in a "unified
budget," a concept adopted in January 1968 (for the FY 1969
Budget). The unified budget provides the bottom-line impact of
all federal spending and taxing on the economy by
indicating--through the cash deficit or surplus--the impact on
credit markets.
The unified budget also consolidates both
operating and capital expenditures, which means that the federal
government does not have a separate budget for capital
expenditures. The receipts and outlays shown in the unified
budget are similar to a cash flow statement in the private
sector, which also provides a comprehensive accounting of income
and spending.
There have been several efforts since World War
II to address the question of whether budget procedures should be
changed to provide for separate consideration of capital and
operating expenditures.(22) For
example, a
capital budget was incorporated in the
Taft-Radcliffe amendment to the Employment Act of 1945, which was
passed by the Senate but rejected in the House. The 1949 Hoover
Commission did not recommend a separate capital budget, but it
did suggest that the government publish budget estimates for
current operating expenditures and capital outlays separately
under each major function or activity in the budget.
There were periodic attempts in Congress during
the subsequent two decades to adopt a capital budget, but these
were often opposed by the executive branch and never resulted in
legislation. The capital budget was firmly rejected in 1967 by
the President's Commission on Budget Concepts, as it was in
previous studies by the American Institute of Certified Public
Accountants and the U.S. Chamber of Commerce. Interest in the
idea returned in the 1980s with the apparent approval of
Comptroller General Charles Bowsher and the suggestion by
President Reagan in 1986 that the idea be studied. Interest in
capital budgeting surfaced again during Congressional
deliberations in 1995-96 over the proposed Balanced Budget
Amendment (BBA) to the Constitution. Some of the proponents of
the BBA wanted the amendment applied only to operating expenses
of the federal government, excluding some defined capital that
could be financed by government debt.
The federal budget process today continues to
budget operating and capital expenditures together.(23) During the course of its deliberations, the
commission
heard several explanations of why this is the case (although not
all commissioners agree with each of them).
First, for reasons already discussed, federal
policy makers have not been able to agree on a single definition
of capital or investment in the public sector. While a technical
analysis that accompanies the budget (today it is known as Analytical
Perspectives) has used a stable definition of investment for
many years, the use of the term investment in the budget to
describe policy proposals has changed with the political
priorities of different administrations.(24)
Given the
changing priorities of the Congress and different administrations
through time, it is not surprising that no single definition of
public capital has emerged.
Second, capital is one of a number of inputs
(along with materials and labor) that the federal government uses
to deliver its services (directly or through state and local
levels of government) to the public. The public, in turn, judges
the government not by the inputs it uses, but by the amount and
perceived quality of the output it delivers. On this view, budget
decisions should focus on the goals to be achieved (such as
providing education or securing the national defense), and not on
the mix between capital and other inputs judged necessary to
achieve them.
Third, although there is no necessary
connection between capital spending and its financing--indeed,
many states, localities, and other authorities have clearly
defined capital budgets without financing all capital through
borrowing--there have been fears that a "capital budget" would allow what is
called capital to be debt-financed
(in large part or in the entirety). Those who believe these
concerns are justified also fear that adoption of a capital
budget could create a strong temptation for policy makers to
classify a wide range of expenditures as capital or investment
(1) to avoid having to pay for them out of tax receipts or (2) to
avoid having them subject to caps on discretionary spending. This
is especially true for high visibility projects for which there
are clear, short-term political benefits to elected officials in
both branches of government who advocate them.
The fears about excessive spending are of
special concern: while it is true that the federal government
cannot borrow without limit, federal borrowing is far less
constrained by financial markets than is the case for borrowing
by private firms and state and local governments. Investors
understand that people and capital can easily move to other
locales if state or local taxes are considered to be too high.
This limits the ability of states and localities to borrow.
Simply put, the added taxes that are required to service their
debts could cause individuals or companies to move to other areas
if they believe that the additional services are not worth the
higher taxes.(25) By contrast,
individuals
and corporations in this
country are far less likely to move to other countries in
response to changes in taxes here. Furthermore, investors also
understand that there is a buyer of last resort for federal
debt--the Federal Reserve, which regularly adds to the money
supply by buying Treasury securities.
Capital Budgeting in Other
Countries
The national governments of very few other
industrialized countries currently have a capital budget. At one
time, Sweden, Denmark, and the Netherlands engaged in the
practice, but all have since abandoned it. However, New Zealand
and more recently the United Kingdom have adopted different
versions of a capital budget for decision-making purposes.
In 1988, New Zealand's national government
introduced a capital budget for government-owned fixed assets.
Spending on these items is separately budgeted and not shown on
the government's operating budget, which is compiled under the
accrual method of accounting. Depreciation of government capital
is reflected on the operating statement, analogous to the way it
would be accounted for in a private business in the income
statement. Nonetheless, the full cost of capital assets must be
appropriated in advance.(26)
In June 1998, the United Kingdom announced an
even bolder capital budgeting initiative. Under this approach,
the British government has established for a three-year period a
budget for all physical investment and grants in support of
capital spending. A two-part financing rule has been announced to
accompany the budget: (1) the "golden rule"
under which the government will borrow only to invest (and not to
support current spending), averaged over the economic cycle; and
(2) a limitation on borrowing to ensure that the public
debt-to-national income ratio is stable over the economic cycle.
The new system was adopted with the explicit intention of
encouraging more spending on public capital, raising net public
investment as a share of GDP from 0.75 percent to 1.5 percent
[Brown, 1998, p. 6].
It is too early to judge the results from
either of these initiatives. Still, at least three features of
the governmental systems in both countries are noteworthy. First,
neither government counts expenditures on education and
R&D--part of what we have labeled "national capital"--as capital for
budgeting purposes. Second, the
governments in both New Zealand and the United Kingdom operate
within a parliamentary system under which the party controlling
the executive branch also controls the majority in the
Parliament. Accordingly, the proposed budget of the executive
branch is expected to be adopted into law, unlike in this
country. Third, agency heads in both New Zealand and the United
Kingdom have greater authority to manage their operations, with
incentive-based pay, than do their counterparts in the United
States.
One feature of the current federal budget
process--the general practice of having the full cost of all
capital acquisitions appropriated by Congress before any portion
of the acquisition can be made or the project started--has been
alleged to act as a bias against public capital investment,
specifically government-owned capital.(27)
The commission
believes, however, that full funding is important because it
ensures that policy makers consider the total costs of an
initiative before authorizing and appropriating the funds for it.
Otherwise, policy makers would be tempted to fund only a portion
of a capital project in the initial years, which means it would
be too far along to stop later. We discuss below how failure to
fully fund projects in the past has produced substantial waste.
Nonetheless, it is possible that
decision-makers defer some necessary, but large, capital projects
because funding them requires authorized spending to "spike" in
a given year. To the extent this occurs, aggregate public
investment may fall short of some ideal figure.
How serious a problem this actually turns out
to be, however, depends to a significant degree on whether
spending is more constrained in any year by the caps on budget
authority or on outlays. As it turns out, the caps on budget
authority (BA) seldom have constrained spending. Instead, in most
years since the BEA was enacted, the outlay caps have been
reached first. As already noted, capital projects also tend to
have low outlay rates--that is, they spend out their budget
authority over several years. When the outlay caps under the BEA
are the binding constraint, the slower outlay rates for capital
projects could induce Congress to spend more than it
otherwise would on public capital. This is because operating
expenses, including maintenance, tend to spend out quickly, and
thus get scored as outlays in the forthcoming budget year.(i) Of course, there are projects so large that even if
the
outlays are spread over several years, the annual outlay is still
a "spike" and spending could be constrained if the outlay caps
are binding.(j)
Efforts to get around budget spikes, meanwhile,
produce distortions of their own. As just noted, agencies can be
tempted to use "camel's nose under the tent" budget
tactics that have led to inefficient outcomes. Another,
potentially wasteful budget maneuver for avoiding spikes is for
agencies (sometimes with Congressional blessing) to enter into
short-term leases rather than to construct or purchase property
at the outset--even when the life-cycle cost of the purchase
would be lower than the cost of stringing together a series of
short-term leases. Both of these "tricks"
demonstrate that seemingly arcane scoring rules can have a real
impact on budget decisions.
Although it may not be possible to determine
whether current budgeting procedures have caused a sub-optimal
amount of total capital spending, there is much greater reason to
believe that the current system generates biases at the micro
level: that is, capital spending is allocated among capital
projects and initiatives, including the maintenance of existing
capital assets, in a less-than-ideal fashion.
The Congressional Budget Office has reviewed
the available studies of the measured economic returns from
different activities, finding a very large variation--from
programs that have produced estimated social returns well in
excess of the cost of capital, to those that are producing almost
no positive returns.(28)
Significantly, the CBO cites evidence
indicating that maintenance can pay social dividends well in
excess of the returns realized on some large new projects [CBO].
The commission recognizes that budgeting is not
a mechanistic exercise solely in search of initiatives with the
highest economic returns.(29)
But in deciding how much attention to pay to
efficiency and how much to distributional objectives, policy
makers must work within a structured framework that (1) confronts
them with the implications of the relevant tradeoffs and (2)
provides maximum incentives for producing cost-effective
decisions. Of particular interest to the commission is the need
for federal decision-makers to take adequate account of the
interests of American society over the long run. The commission
has concluded, however, that in several respects, the current
budget process impedes the ability of decision-makers to achieve
these important objectives.
To understand the basis for this conclusion, we
first briefly review the key phases of the current federal budget
cycle, and then discuss its shortcomings.
The "budget process" of any organization is
usefully understood as the
combination of four important, separate functions: planning and
analysis, which leads to budget recommendations; the making of
budget decisions; accounting and reporting of the results; and
evaluation of the outcomes of budget decisions and subsequent
readjustment in programs, where appropriate. We have already
described the legal process by which budget decisions are made.
At the risk of some over-simplification, here are some key
features that explain how the federal government carries out the
other three functions.
The process begins generally 18 months in
advance of each fiscal year at the agency level, when individual
departments and agencies develop internally the budget requests
they will make to the President (initially through OMB) for that
fiscal year. Until relatively recently, with few exceptions,
agencies focused their budget plans only on a single year and
generally paid little attention to their long-run plans. This
changed to some extent with the enactment of the Government
Performance and Results Act of 1993 (GPRA), which requires
agencies to submit five-year strategic plans to OMB every three
years. The first such plan was submitted in 1997, the next one is
due in 2000.
For the most part, the strategic plans are
descriptive in nature and do not contain out-year
spending/revenue projections. Nonetheless, the agencies separately
provide to OMB their spending and revenue projections five years
out under presidential policy. OMB uses these projections to
present in the President's annual budget five-year projections of
revenue, by major source, and outlays in aggregated form and at
the function and program level (OMB's data base includes
projections at the "account"level beyond the budget year, but these are not shown in the
budget).
The GPRA requires agencies to submit
performance plans to OMB and the Congress each year. The Act also
requires OMB to prepare a government-wide plan. These plans, the
first of which was submitted with the President's budget for FY
1999, are supposed to lay out the agencies' goals in objective,
quantifiable terms (such as the airplane accident rate for the
Federal Aviation Administration) for that budget year.
Agencies also prepare balance sheets that
report their assets and liabilities. The Chief Financial Officers
Act of 1990 required all cabinet departments, major independent
agencies and the government as a whole to have audited financial
statements. These financial statements are prepared in accordance
with federal accounting standards developed by the Federal
Accounting Standards Advisory Board (FASAB).(30) Of particular interest to this commission,
these standards require the financial statements to disclose in
footnote form estimates of deferred maintenance, effective with
the statements for fiscal 1998. In his fiscal year 1999 budget,
the President set a goal of having an unqualified opinion on the
consolidated (government-wide) financial statements for that
year. Furthermore, twenty of the twenty-four agencies under this
Act are committed to obtaining unqualified opinions on their own
statements in the same time frame [OMB and CFO Council, 1998].
Various mechanisms are in place for evaluating
the outcomes and ongoing progress of federal programs. The
agencies typically have evaluation efforts under way. Congress
periodically asks the General Accounting Office to prepare
independent evaluations. Nonetheless, no ongoing systematic,
government-wide evaluation process is in place, whether for
capital spending (however defined) or other types of spending.
As reflected in the foregoing summary, a number
of significant improvements have been made in recent years in
certain stages of the federal budget process. Even so, the
commission has concluded that the existing process, at each of
its various stages, still contains a number of important
shortcomings. A broad theme that ties the various flaws together
is that the federal government--both the executive and
legislative branches considered together--is so heavily focused
on each current budget year that too little attention is paid to
longer-run matters. Furthermore, policy makers are not held
sufficiently accountable for the longer-run implications of their
current decisions. This shows up in part in wasteful spending on
some capital projects, a shortchanging of maintenance of existing
assets, and perhaps some missed opportunities (which are
inherently difficult to measure, but nonetheless real).
The tendency toward surplus in some trust funds
has become a problem under current scoring rules. Specifically,
these rules treat revenues going into the trust funds on the
mandatory side of the budget, but classify the spending out of
the trust funds as discretionary spending and thus subject to
caps. Congress and the administration took a major step toward
rectifying the imbalance in the highway trust fund generated by
this difference in scoring with the enactment of the
Transportation Equity Act for the 21st Century in 1998. This
legislation creates separate BEA caps for highway and mass
transit spending, and it sets the caps equal to the receipts from
motor fuels taxes collected the previous year.(31)
The commission does not endorse the specific
spending formula in this act as a model for other trust funds;
however, it does believe that the principle of tying spending out
of the capital-related trust funds to the tax and fee revenue
that flows into them, averaged over some reasonable time period,
is a good one to follow.
The current budget decision-making process also
exerts biases against both routine and major maintenance, such as
rehabilitation and remodeling (which represents a different type
of capital expenditure). As already noted, the presence of the
outlay caps feeds such a bias because the budget authority for
both types of maintenance has associated with it a more rapid
outlay rate than budget authority for new construction. In
addition, there currently is no mechanism assuring that state and
local governments receiving federal support for new capital
projects adequately maintain those assets, once they have been
constructed or acquired (nor do rating agencies generally allow
maintenance to be bonded). This can defer maintenance, in turn
leading to excessive funding for new assets when it may be more
cost-effective to maintain existing assets.
The shortchanging of maintenance is aggravated
by the lack of accurate and timely information on the condition
of federal and federally funded assets. Granted, recently adopted
federal financial accounting standards require the audited
financial statements of the agencies to be accompanied by
footnotes disclosing the extent of deferred maintenance; yet
footnote disclosure is not a substitute for a more complete and
detailed report on the actual condition of federally owned
assets. In addition, the federal government's financial
statements do not contain information on the condition of assets
at the state and local levels, some of which the federal
government has funded.(32)
Information about the current condition and
even obsolescence of assets is critical if policy makers are to
design effective maintenance and capital spending programs.
The commission cannot stress too strongly the
importance of having reliable estimates of deferred maintenance.
Currently, there is no generally accepted method for agencies to
use in estimating deferred maintenance. This is a significant
shortcoming since sound policy making requires having accurate
information of deferred maintenance in setting spending
priorities and in deciding whether to purchase new assets or fix
existing ones. This shortcoming has led the FASAB to propose an
amendment to its current standards that would relax the audit
requirement for the information reported on deferred maintenance.
In conjunction with this change, OMB is planning to organize a
task force to develop methods for making consistent,
government-wide estimates of deferred maintenance, which should
enable these estimates to be fully audited. Still, until better
and more-consistent information about the condition of federally
owned and financed assets is routinely made available, policy
makers will be unable to make fully informed decisions about
whether to fund new projects or put more money toward maintaining
existing assets.
Though efforts have been made to evaluate the
effectiveness of government programs, we believe there is still
little systematic retrospective analysis within either branch of
the federal government to determine whether capital projects
generated the benefits and came within the cost projections that
were originally promised.
In sum, we recognize that it is difficult to
determine whether the existing budget process produces
insufficient or excessive amounts of capital spending in the
aggregate; however, there are several reasons for believing that
aspects of the process contribute to a sub-optimal allocation of
capital spending among various projects while shortchanging
maintenance.
RECOMMENDATIONS
The commission considered a range of proposals
to address the problems that have just been identified. We
believe the appropriate response is to make improvements in each
of the component parts of the budget process. Many of the
recommendations we outline below relate to improvements in
information, but others also entail changes in the ways that
budget decisions are actually considered and made.
Better Planning and
Analysis
Long-range planning for all kinds of
expenditures and operations of the federal government is
essential (1) to ensure that services are delivered to the public
in the most-effective manner and (2) to allow policy makers to
judge how much and what kinds of capital are needed to provide
public services.(33)
Given the difficulty of terminating programs
and initiatives once begun, the preparation and publication of
long-run plans can help ensure that resources are wisely
committed to new programs before they are launched, while
facilitating ongoing readjustment in priorities when appropriate.
The commission advances the following recommendations to help
improve this process.
Recommendation 1: Five-Year Strategic
Plans
Although the GPRA made major strides in
requiring agencies to prepare five-year plans, we have pointed to
a number of gaps in the existing planning process that should be
filled.
First, the five-year plans should be prepared
annually (not just every three years) and should be integrated
with the annual performance plans. Furthermore, the plans should
be an integral part of the budget justifications sent to
Congress.
Second, the plans should be reconciled with the
longer-run budget projections that the agencies already submit to
OMB. In particular, the plans need to state results-oriented
objectives--not just for the current budget year under current
budget policy, but ideally with respect to future projected
changes in policy.
Third, the plans and annual budgets should be
tied to the life-cycles of the agencies' capital assets. The
following elements of capital planning are common in the private
sector and among state and local governments, and should be
standard practice for the federal government: a needs assessment
for such additional capital assets; a realistic maintenance
schedule, funded appropriately; and recognized replacement
cycles.
Fourth, OMB should develop standardized formats
for the plans (in consultation with GAO and CBO) so that policy
makers in both the executive and legislative branches can more
easily compare the plans of one agency to another. Among other
things, the plans should be less voluminous than many currently
are, should record past successes in achieving defined
results-oriented objectives, should identify shortcomings that
need to be addressed, and should spot challenges that remain to
be tackled. The plans should also identify major future outlays
for physical assets (segregated in a separate "capital acquisition fund," as discussed
below) in a level of detail that OMB should specify.
Fifth, OMB should expand its efforts to
evaluate the plans (together with benefit-cost analyses of major
projects, as discussed below) and to consider them in connection
with government-wide planning. Among other things, the plans
should help identify programs and efforts that are no longer
needed, programs that might be better carried out by other
federal agencies or other levels of government, and new programs
that may be truly necessary. The results of this exercise should
be considered in the preparation of the President's annual
budget.
Sixth, in considering agency appropriation
requests, the Congress should take account of the agencies'
five-year plans and of OMB's annual evaluations of those plans,
as reflected in the President's budget. Congressional
authorization, appropriations, budget resolution, and oversight
hearings should focus on these plans and evaluations. Congress
should also study ways in which it might improve its own
procedures to give more weight to the longer-run implications of
its current year decisions and to issues with longer-run
consequences. In undertaking this task, Congress might find it
useful to take advantage of the wide range of institutional
expertise available to it, including resources within the
Congressional Budget Office, the General Accounting Office, and
the Congressional Research Service.
Recommendation 2: Benefit-Cost Assessments
The benefits and costs (both expressed in
monetary terms to the extent practical) of alternative options
should be considered before decisions are made. This principle
has been part of executive branch regulatory rulemaking (for "major"
rules) for over two decades. It has recently been required of
federal capital projects as well through OMB's Capital
Programming Guide.
The commission believes that several extensions
beyond existing practice are warranted. First, the benefit-cost
requirement should be extended beyond federally owned capital
assets to the broader array of undertakings associated with a
definition of national capital. To some extent, this is already
done, although not in a systematic fashion. Most agencies fund
evaluations of their programs. We are suggesting that the
evaluation process become more systematic and institutionalized.
Policy makers should not wait for sporadic economic studies of
individual programs prepared by academic scholars to appear in
the professional literature. Instead, there should be an ongoing
effort within the government to analyze the benefits and costs of
all major programs--whether or not related to capital
expenditures--so that they can be adjusted, refashioned, or
eliminated, as appropriate. As a practical matter, it may be
useful to begin by requiring benefit-cost analyses only for "major"
initiatives, such as those over a certain dollar threshold; later
on, smaller capital projects and government programs could be
analyzed in the same fashion.
Second, more resources within the agencies,
OMB, CBO, and GAO, should be devoted to carrying out this
mission. Those resources should also support OMB in its effort to
become a clearinghouse for "best practices" in evaluation
techniques that the agencies can and
should draw upon in preparing their own analyses. Given the many
billions of dollars at stake each year, it would be penny-wise
and pound-foolish not to spend millions of dollars for analysis
to help produce better information for decision-makers in both
branches of government and for the public. (A related need is for
the government to provide a stronger commitment to improving its
base of statistical data on the entire economy. Some of this
information is important in preparing benefit-cost and other
analyses of various existing and proposed government programs.)
Third, working with the agencies, OMB should
periodically review the evaluation techniques they use and, where
appropriate, provide guidance to improve them.
Improving the Decision-Making
Process
The commission believes that several measures
short of adopting a separate "capital" budget could improve the quality of budget policy
decisions. These recommendations are set forth below.
Recommendation 3: Capital Acquisition Funds
As an experiment, the commission believes it
would be useful for Congress and the executive branch to have one
or more agencies with capital-intensive operations establish a
separate "capital acquisition fund" (CAF) within
their budgets that would receive appropriations for the
construction and acquisition of large capital projects. The CAFs
would use that authority to borrow from the Treasury's general
fund and then charge operating units within the agency rents
equal to the debt service (interest and amortization) on those
projects.(34)
In addition, the CAFs would acquire all
existing capital assets of the agency so that all the costs of
all such capital could be allocated within the agency.
To ensure uniform implementation of the
proposal, OMB should issue guidance about what capital items
belong in the CAFs, such as federal buildings and other large
capital purchases by the agencies.(35)
The main advantage of CAFs is that they should
improve the process of planning and budgeting within agencies. If
units or divisions within agencies are charged the true costs of
their space and other large capital items, they are likely to
make more efficient use of those assets. CAFs could also help
address the spike problem by smoothing out the budget authority
required for any large capital projects proposed by units within
agencies. In principle, Congress could take this smoothing
function one level higher by either formally or informally
budgeting CAFs across all of the agencies within the
jurisdictions of each of the thirteen appropriations
subcommittees. However, there is still merit in having CAFs
managed at the agency level to promote accountability.(36)
If the CAF experiments realize the foregoing
benefits, the commission would urge that CAFs be used for all
agencies.
Clearly, the CAFs would not replace the General
Services Administration, which manages the Federal Buildings Fund
(FBF), a government-wide revolving fund established in 1972. The
FBF acquires office buildings and rents space in them to federal
agencies. The GSA can and does delegate its authority to agencies
to acquire their own office space under some circumstances. In
such cases, an agency would acquire its office space through its
CAF. Greater use of this delegation authority would be
appropriate if agencies could demonstrate that the CAFs led them
to improve their capital asset management practices. In addition,
GSA would negotiate the acquisition of space for multiple
agencies that seek to co-locate in a single facility.
Recommendation 4: Full Funding for Capital
Projects
Full funding of capital projects encourages
decision-makers to consider the life-cycle costs and benefits of
projects before they are undertaken and to compare the funding
required with other governmental priorities. This practice should
be continued.
Nonetheless, large projects in particular may
produce funding spikes that may cause the postponement of such
initiatives in favor of smaller, less cost-effective projects, or
even their cancellation. This problem can be addressed, without
sacrificing the principle of full funding, by providing advance
appropriations for all useful and programmatically separate
segments of particular projects. A useful segment is one in which
the benefits exceed the costs even if no further funding is
appropriated. For example, if the full project envisions
acquisition of multiple aircraft, a useful segment would be the
number of aircraft for which benefits exceed costs even if no
additional aircraft are ever authorized.
The preparation of five-year plans by the
agencies should also help remedy the spike problem by alerting
OMB and the Congress to potential future funding needs for large
projects. If policy makers become aware of these requirements,
they might be able to better adjust their annual appropriations
accordingly.
Recommendation 5: Adhering to the Scoring
Rules for Leasing
In principle, the scoring rules in the BEA are
designed to eliminate any bias that policy makers might have in
deciding whether to acquire or lease capital assets used in the
delivery of government services. They do this by requiring the
present value of so-called capital leases--those that are the
functional equivalent of a purchase--to be scored up front, as if
they were purchases; in this way, policy makers can make accurate
comparisons between the two options and decide which is the least
expensive. Under the current BEA rules, which are modeled after
private sector accounting standards, a capital lease is one in
which (1) the lease transfers ownership of the property by the
end of the lease term, (2) the net present value of the lease
payments is at least 90 percent of the fair value of the
property, or (3) the term of the lease is at least 75 percent of
the expected life of the asset.
The current rules give the agencies and
Congress an incentive to be creative. Specifically, they can
enter into a succession of shorter-term leases that do not meet
the quantitative criteria for defining a capital lease precisely,
which means the full cost of the lease does not need to be scored
up front. Although this is legal under the current rules, it can
result in wasteful spending when, computed appropriately on a
present value basis, the less expensive alternative is to buy the
asset.
In principle, this problem could be remedied by
a rule that required the capitalization of all short-term lease
payments expected in the future. To be effective, however, this
rule would require strict scrutiny of estimates of future lease
payments--something that may be difficult and expensive to do in
its own right.(k)
In addition, there is a risk that any rule
requiring the capitalization of all leases could discourage the
use of short-term leases that are highly cost-effective, such as
when agencies are downsizing or between moves to different
locations.
Though the commission believes that the best
course for now is to retain the existing BEA rule, both the
agencies and the Congress should strictly adhere to it. This
should be easier to do when agencies are preparing strategic
plans every year. These plans could expose the intentions of the
agencies with respect to capital assets in particular. In turn,
OMB and Congress would be able to identify programs where
purchase is more suitable than leasing, as well as become alert
to possible spending spikes that could be smoothed by the other
recommendations already outlined (CAFs and advance funding for
useful, separate project segments).(l)
Recommendation 6: Trust Fund Reforms
Various trust funds--for highways, airports,
the air traffic control system, water projects, and certain other
purposes--have been created with the ostensible purpose of
assuring the funding of capital projects. The funds have been
financed with fees or taxes assessed on those who use the
facilities (such as the gasoline tax to help support highway
construction and the airline passenger ticket tax to help fund
airport equipment and construction).
The commission believes two important reforms
of current trust funds are necessary to make them more
cost-effective.
First, averaged over some reasonable period
such as three years, the revenues from taxes and fees dedicated
to the trust funds supporting infrastructure or capital spending
should be spent for designated purposes: capital spending and
maintenance. OMB should highlight in either the budget or
accompanying documents the extent to which trust fund monies are
being spent for such purposes. If spending on the earmarked uses
is not sufficient to exhaust the revenues over some reasonable
period, then Congress should lower the specific taxes or fees so
that the revenue they raise is more in line with the spending
they are intended to finance.
Second, state and local governments that
receive federal support for capital items (such as
highways)--whether or not such support is provided through a
trust fund--should be required to maintain assets financed by the
federal government as a condition of receiving any additional
federal support. The one possible exception to this general rule
is where state and local governments can demonstrate that the
assets the federal government initially funded are no longer
needed (as could be the case with roads in rural areas where the
population has dwindled). Otherwise, the federal government risks
financing new infrastructure that may be unnecessary. States and
localities seeking federal aid for capital projects should be
required to certify that they have met the maintenance
requirement, and the relevant federal agencies should check these
certifications. To the extent that this maintenance requirement
represents an "unfunded mandate," the
commission believes it is one that could readily be justified as
a mechanism to help ensure the efficiency of spending at all
levels of government on federally supported capital projects.(37)
Recommendation 7: Incentives for Asset
Management
In addition to improving the information
available to decision-makers and changing the scoring rules, it
is important that agencies have financial incentives to manage
their assets efficiently. In the private sector, firms clearly
have such incentives; the better they manage, the more money they
are likely to make.
Federal agencies operate under much tighter
constraints in managing their assets than is the case in the
private sector. With few exceptions, agencies cannot sell,
exchange, or lease assets on their own. Instead, if they no
longer have a use for certain property, they must report it as "excess" to
the General Services Administration. In turn, the GSA must first
offer it to other federal agencies; if no agency claims it, the
property can then be offered to state and local governments and
various non-profit organizations.
The commission encourages the administration
and the Congress to expand the freedom of agencies to manage
their assets and to consider ways to give the agencies incentives
to do so efficiently. One possibility would be to allow, on an
experimental basis, one or more agencies to keep a limited
portion of the revenues they raise from selling or renting out
existing assets.
Better Information
The third stage in the budget process is the
reporting of the results. The commission recommends two key
improvements in this area.
Recommendation 8: Clarification of the
Federal Budget Presentation
Policy makers must be cognizant of the
cumulative impact of their many micro budget decisions when
planning how much to spend on individual government programs or
deciding to alter the tax code. In short, they shouldn't lose
sight of the forest when planting individual trees. The forest
should be plainly visible for the American people to see, in
user-friendly form.
One set of forest level figures, of course,
includes the aggregate totals of spending and revenue, and the
resulting projected deficit or surplus in the unified budget. In
recent years, the goal of a balanced budget has been the guiding
principle for decision-making about the budget. In addition,
given the strictures of the caps, policy makers necessarily pay
attention to the broad spending breakdowns defined by the Budget
Enforcement Act--namely the distinction between mandatory and
discretionary spending and within the latter, the distinction
between defense and non-defense spending.
The commission believes policy makers also
should pay attention to another set of broad categories of
spending: operating expenditures (defense and non-defense),
investment spending, transfer payments made to individuals, and
interest on the federal debt. Apart from the fact that federal
policy makers do not budget depreciation, the separation of
operating and investment spending would be analogous to a similar
division used in the private sector and in most state and local
governments. The breakout of transfer payments to individuals is
useful because of the federal government's deep involvement in
this area, protecting individuals against financial losses due to
unemployment, retirement, disability, and illness. Interest on
the federal debt should be reported separately because it is a
financing expense rather than an operating expenditure.
Table 4 below is illustrative of the type of
information that should be highlighted in future budget
presentations, with the notes below explaining how the figures
displayed were calculated.(m) The
definition of investment, in particular, is a broad
one, as it includes not only spending on federal assets, but also
federal spending on education and R&D, as well as federal
capital grants to states and localities. Since the definitions of
investment spending in particular may vary from administration to
administration, it would be useful if something like Table 4 were
constructed using alternative definitions of investment. Also of
use would be a chart showing historical trends in spending in the
different categories, especially as a percentage of GDP, as well
as projected future spending in the various categories. This
should be supplemented with charts or tables showing expected
changes in the net capital stock for major categories of physical
assets.
For policy makers, the kind of information just
described would highlight to what extent the President proposes
to invest for the future, to operate the federal government's
various functions (excluding depreciation, which is not counted
as spending under current budget accounting concepts), and to
arrange for transfers to qualifying individuals. It would also
explain how spending for all these activities may be constrained
by the obligation to pay interest on the cumulative amount of
federal debt.
No sensible private firm would decide whether
to undertake a new investment, such as a new building or plant,
without detailed knowledge of the composition, condition, and
value of its existing facilities. Yet for decades the federal
government operated this way, without having an updated and
accurate inventory and report of the condition of its own
assets--let alone those of the other levels of government to
which it routinely makes grants. Moreover, public policy debates
about national priorities have not been as well informed as they
should have been. Specifically there has been no easy way for the
public, the media, or even expert analysts to evaluate such
questions as whether there is an "infrastructure deficit," or whether budget
cuts to reduce the unified federal
budget deficit were achieved through sensible economies or by
neglecting improvements or additions to the preexisting public
capital stock.
As discussed earlier, the CFO Act of 1990 makes
major strides in rectifying this situation by requiring
individual federal agencies and the government as a whole to
issue audited financial statements. Furthermore, work is planned
for developing standardized methods for estimating deferred
maintenance. The commission strongly supports these efforts and
encourages OMB to work with the agencies to complete this task
promptly.
One important consequence of the CFO Act is
that the federal government now publishes consolidated financial
statements. These share two important principles with private
financial accounting practices that are essential to objective,
consistent, and trusted reporting: (1) the use of definitions
based on independently determined accounting standards
(determined by FASAB), which are designed to be insulated from
the political process; and (2) the independent auditing of the
financial data, which helps assure the public that the
information is not manipulated to achieve political ends.
Still, more should be done.
First, the calculation of depreciation in
various government reports should be standardized. Currently,
depreciation of capital items reported in the Analytical
Perspectives volume of the President's budget is computed
with reference to the replacement cost of the assets, whereas
depreciation reported on financial statements is based on
historical costs of assets. This kind of inconsistency should be
eliminated so that depreciation is reported consistently in all
government financial reports.
Second, the agencies should make their audited
financial statements, together with detailed breakdowns of assets
and their condition, widely available in printed form and through
publication on their websites. The financial statements should
continue to be prepared on the basis of independently developed
accounting standards.
Third, this information should also be
consolidated at the government-wide level, either by OMB or GAO.
The resulting aggregate report, with appropriate detailed
breakdowns by agency and type of investment, should also be
audited and published in written and electronic form.
The annual audited statements, together with
the detailed breakdowns on the condition of federally owned
assets, will be valuable tools for the agencies in preparing
their longer-term strategies, for preparation of the President's
annual budget, and for Congress in both assessing the agencies'
out-year plans and deciding on current year appropriations.
Policy makers and analysts would also be able to use the
consolidated report, in conjunction with the information on the
condition of federally owned assets, to judge the setting of
priorities across the government and to assess whether the
government has unmet needs that are likely to show up in future
budgets. Furthermore, the report would enhance the public's
ability to understand how and to what extent their tax dollars
are being spent on current activities or used to increase the
public capital stock. It would also reveal, for example, whether
the capital stock was growing at an unreasonably rapid rate, or
at the other extreme, contracting.
Fourth, the consolidated reports should provide
information based on multiple concepts of investment, including
the current FASAB definition of government investment as well as
alternative concepts the public and the Congress might find
useful. Toward this end, FASAB should examine the feasibility of
developing alternative definitions--especially those that take
account of investments in human capital and other intangible
assets. Multiple views of investment would promote better
understanding of the federal government's past use of resources
and its current needs.
The commission believes there should be better
information on the condition of existing assets. As previously
noted, work is planned at the federal level for agencies to begin
developing standardized methods for estimating deferred
maintenance. The commission strongly supports these efforts and
encourages OMB to work with the agencies to complete this task
promptly and implement its results. In combination with the rest
of the information provided in the audited financial statements,
data on deferred maintenance will enable policy makers to develop
sound plans for maintaining existing assets and spending on new
ones, where that is advisable.
OMB should also work with the agencies to
compile an annual report on the condition of state and local
infrastructure, or at least on that portion that has been
federally assisted. The commission recognizes that this is a
major, long-term undertaking and requires the cooperation of
state and local governments to help identify what data are
available and additional information that needs to be collected.
This endeavor may also call for federal legislation requiring the
states and localities to report information about their assets to
the federal government. But in this "information age,"
there is no reason for citizens and policy makers throughout the
country--and especially those at the federal level--to remain
unaware of the condition of assets that have been financed or
supported with federal tax dollars.
Finally, it is critical that the federal
government have mechanisms in place for constantly evaluating the
outcomes of budget decisions. Many agencies already do this
(although with varying degrees of success). Still, there is room
for improvement.
In particular, a natural companion to the
recommendation that the benefits and costs of major capital
projects be assessed before they are undertaken, is that
the agencies, under OMB's guidance and review, should (1)
regularly conduct benefit-cost analyses of existing major capital
spending initiatives and (2) report the results in a manner
useful for decision-makers and the public. Such a "Report Card,"
which could be included in the annual Analytical
Perspectives that accompanies the budget, could identify
which investment projects have produced returns to society in
excess of some benchmark "cost of capital"--such as the prevailing
interest rate on long-term
federal debt, the average cost of capital expected by private
investors, or other thresholds that OMB determines useful to the
public. Furthermore, it is important that the agencies and OMB
use such existing mechanisms as the Government Performance and
Results Act (GPRA), the Federal Acquisition Streamlining Act
(FASA), and the Clinger-Cohen Act to evaluate public investment
programs. In this way, policy makers can make mid-course
alterations, if feasible, and learn from the successes and
weaknesses of past efforts to help produce wise spending
decisions in the future.
To be sure, not all programs have benefits that
can be easily quantified, let alone expressed in monetary terms.
Indeed, the commission recognizes that the projects in which it
may be feasible to provide a monetary analysis may account for a
relatively small fraction of total spending; nonetheless, over
time, advances in estimating techniques may permit a larger
fraction of total spending to be evaluated in this manner.
Furthermore, as in the regulatory sphere, OMB and the agencies
should do the best they can with the available data. Where the
benefits of projects cannot be measured in monetary terms, the
evaluations should identify the objectives of the projects and
assess their benefits qualitatively. Meanwhile, OMB should take
the lead in identifying ways to improve both the collection of
information useful to such analyses and analytic techniques.
PROS AND CONS OF A "CAP" ON
CAPITAL SPENDING
There is no inherent reason that a capital
budgeting process used for decision-making must be linked with
any particular financing rule. In principle, capital spending
could be subject to an appropriations process separate from the
one used for operating expenditures. To ensure spending
restraint, a separate cap on capital spending could also be
imposed.
Most members of the commission do not support a
capital spending cap. Several commissioners, however, believe
that moving in this direction might be appropriate, but with the
understanding that it would require a change in the way both the
executive and legislative branches do business (which might be
facilitated by a study involving representatives of both
branches).
In this section, we discuss issues that would
have to be resolved if Congress and the administration were to
agree on including a separate cap on capital spending (under some
definition) as part of the budget process, as well as some
implications of taking such a step. In the process, we outline
arguments in favor of and against making this change in budget
procedures. This discussion assumes the continuation of the
spending caps that are now part of the Budget Enforcement Act.
Implementation Issues
A cap on capital spending could not be
implemented for decision-making until at least the following
three issues are resolved:
First, how would capital be defined? A key
argument against adopting a capital cap is that there is
currently no consensus on what definition would be most
useful--or even whether any form of capital spending should be
broken out and treated differently for budget purposes.
Furthermore, if on the one hand, capital spending eventually is
financed at least in part by borrowing, the temptation to expand
the definition will grow. On the other hand, if a separate cap is
imposed without a financing rule, it could impart a bias against
any investment expenditures left out of the definition of
capital.
Those favoring a separate capital cap argue
that as long as policy makers identify a specific objective, a
definition of capital would follow more easily. Indeed, if
Congress were inclined to adopt the idea of a cap, it could ask
FASAB, CBO, or some other body to provide it with recommended
definitions of capital and then decide to use one of them.
Second, on what basis should any capital
spending cap or target be set? Critics of the idea argue that
there is no objective method for answering this question,
especially if capital is broadly defined to include, say, all
national assets. Indeed, as mentioned earlier in this report,
there is no way to know whether or not the current budget process
has a macro bias precisely because it is impossible to make an
objective statement about the optimal level of broadly defined
public capital.
Supporters of a capital budget cap have several
responses to this. One is that policy makers already routinely
make tradeoffs of programs with diverse objectives in the current
budget process, and it would be no different if they were asked
to do so specifically for all capital spending; indeed, having a
national discussion on that issue would be helpful. Another
response is that setting a limit on capital spending would become
conceptually more manageable if capital were more narrowly
defined to be consistent with a single objective.
Third, How exactly would Congress implement a
capital cap? One answer is that Congress could simply set a
non-binding target for capital spending in the annual
budget resolution. A more ambitious step would be to impose a
statutory cap that would actually constrain total appropriations
for capital spending. Presumably, the appropriations committees
would divide up the capital total among each of the thirteen
appropriations subcommittees, as they do now with the so-called
section "302(b)" discretionary spending
allocations.(38)
Critics of the idea would argue that there is
no way to guarantee that spending within any capital allocation
is truly for capital rather than just labeled as such. Supporters
would respond that as long as Congress agreed upon a definition
of capital, an independent scorekeeper like CBO would ensure
faithful implementation of the cap.
Implications
We turn next to the implications of setting a
cap on capital expenditures (under some definition) that both
proponents and opponents of the idea have claimed.
Impact on Budgetary Choices
Advocates of such a cap argue that it would
have at least two salutary effects: it would focus greater
attention on the total amount of resources devoted to achieving
longer-run objectives, and it would improve the allocation of
limited resources toward the most cost-effective initiatives.
Opponents of a separate cap on capital spending
have several responses, apart from those already outlined in the
rest of this report. Arguably, the claimed macro and micro
benefits of a cap could be attained through the improved
reporting requirements and longer-term agency spending plans we
recommend, without running the risks of several potential adverse
consequences. Also, as already discussed, any definition of
capital could create a bias in favor of those items included
within the definition while disadvantaging any capital or other
items that might fall outside it. This problem might be
mitigated, of course, to the extent that policy makers defined
capital broadly--if not initially, then in later years. But a
more expansive definition might weaken budget discipline, which
could lead to excessive public borrowing.
Impact on Budget Discipline
In principle, budget discipline would not be
weakened if a capital budget were adopted without any rule that
capital--gross or net--be financed by borrowing. Indeed,
advocates of a capital budget might argue that a separate cap on
public capital spending would promote budget discipline at the
micro level, where limited resources are allocated among
alternative uses. If policy makers were explicitly required to
trade off different types of capital spending, they might be more
careful about which capital projects they authorize.
Critics of a separate cap on capital spending
argue that it would tempt policy makers to adopt a
borrowing-for-investment rule precisely because capital is
identified with the long run. Future generations, after all, will
reap the benefits of such spending, so why not have them incur
the cost of financing it as well? To the extent public investment
becomes debt-financed as a matter of course, policy makers would
then have incentives to move expenditures within the definition
of capital so that they could be debt-financed. This could lead
to excessive government borrowing, which would lower economic
growth by diverting national saving away from potentially more
productive uses in the private sector.(n)
In addition, future generations might not
appreciate the benefits of programs or projects authorized many
years before, nor might the programs be suitable for the intended
beneficiaries.
More broadly, with present expenditure programs
and taxes, the federal government will apparently run surpluses
in the unified budget, under current budget conventions, for some
years to come--although these projections (which have often
proved to be incorrect in the past) could miss the mark in the
future. The country needs, and does not have, policies and
procedures for deciding how big those surpluses should be,
assuming the projections of surplus prove to be reasonably
accurate.
Deciding how much of a surplus (in the unified
budget) to achieve is difficult. Federal surpluses add to the
national saving, the source from which private investment can be
financed, and thus contribute to economic growth. Logically, the
proper size of the surplus should depend on the rate of private
saving, on expected technological advance, and on expected change
in the size and composition of the population. It should also
represent a social choice between the consumption of the present
generation and the consumption of future generations. To
recommend how these and probably other relevant variables should
be taken into account in deciding on the proper size of the
budget surplus is beyond the charge, as well as the competence,
of this commission. We do, however, want to recognize that in
such a process, some weight might be given to the amount of
federal investment as a factor influencing the proper size of the
surplus. In rejecting both the Balanced Budget Amendment as well
as a simplistic capital budget that would finance all capital
with debt, we do not mean to reject consideration of the total
amount of federal capital (however it is defined) in developing a
more sophisticated fiscal policy in the future.
Impact on Macroeconomic
Stability
It is difficult to reach firm conclusions, in
the abstract, concerning the impact a cap on capital spending
would have on fiscal policy and hence on macroeconomic stability.
The effect of federal fiscal policy on the rest of the economy in
any given year is typically measured by the change in
the structural budget balance (the surplus or deficit assuming
some given level of economic activity, typically full
employment). Each year, in the course of agreeing on a budget,
Congress and the administration together decide how large or
small that change in the structural fiscal balance should be. The
commission cannot say with any degree of certainty whether the
adoption of a separate capital cap would systematically move
fiscal policy in the direction of stimulus or contraction.
An issue related to depreciation is the
following proposal offered by certain individuals who testified
before the commission: that the budgeting for capital be switched
from the current convention, under which the full cost of capital
projects is appropriated up front, to a system of accrual
accounting, in which the costs of such projects (and therefore
their appropriations) would be spread out over their useful
lives. Such a change in scoring would have the following
objective: to remove the alleged bias under the current system
against capital spending that arises because large capital
expenditures can cause spending to bump up against, and even
exceed, the caps on discretionary spending.
Earlier, however, we suggested that there was
no clear evidence as to whether or not this was occurring. But
even if it were, proper accrual accounting requires depreciation
of existing as well as new capital. Table 5 suggests that
investment net of depreciation is substantially below the level
of gross investment spending (although both could be very
different under a system of accrual budgeting).
Realizing this, some have argued that the
scoring of capital items should be changed only for future projects.
Depreciation on existing assets would be ignored. But this would
mean that new capital projects would not have to compete for
resources with previously approved projects. The commission
strongly rejects this approach, which clearly would be
inconsistent with standard accrual accounting practices.
Moreover, if the federal government were to adopt accrual-based
budgeting, it would be inappropriate to confine it to the scoring
of capital. Other programs, including federal insurance and
pensions, would deserve accrual budgeting as well. In fact, these
programs, which now appear to be well financed when scored on a
cash basis, also have large liabilities; consequently, when
scored on an accrual basis, they would imply a much larger level
of total federal spending than the amount now being reported.
Decision-makers could then decide to curtail rather than expand
capital spending (which is not the objective of some of those who
have urged the adoption of accrual budgeting).
FOOTNOTES
1. The
full text of the initial order and subsequent amendments are
shown in Appendix A. Other materials the commission examined in
carrying out its duties, including summaries and full versions of
the testimony the commission heard from a variety of experts and
interested parties, are posted on the website of the commission
at: www.whitehouse.gov/pcscb.
2. The
staff from the various organizations who provided assistance to
the commission are listed in the Acknowledgements.
a. Comment of
Commissioners Corzine, Kramer,
Leone, Levy, O'Cleireacain, Rattner, and Rubin: We wish to
register our strong opposition to any amendment to the
Constitution that would mandate balanced federal budgets. The
macroeconomic straightjacket implied by such a change in the
Constitution would cost the nation dearly in lost growth,
unnecessary unemployment, and slow recovery from recessions.
Indeed, were such an amendment to pass, it would be essential
that many spending items be exempted routinely, while others be
exempted under clearly defined circumstances. Rather than
simplify the budget process, it would then become more confused
and opaque. In addition, democratic governance would suffer since
the ability of Congress and the president to respond to public
priorities would be unduly constrained.
Specifically, in a
recession tax receipts fall and spending for such items as
unemployment insurance rises. This imbalance offsets recessionary
forces, thus speeding recovery. It is one of the reasons economic
downturns have been less severe since World War II than before.
Indeed, the insistence on trying to balance the budget in the
early 1930s is generally considered to have deepened the Great
Depression. The counter-cyclical advantages of the current system
are not trivial. Giving them up may lead to real costs,
particularly among working men and women: income lost when
government cannot fight a recession is lost forever.
b. Comment
of
Commissioners Lynn,
Penner, and Stein: We do not favor adopting at this time a
capital budget of any kind, whether of the kind here labeled "simplistic" or any other known to
us. We endorse the qualification "at this time" to allow for the possibility that future
developments in information, sophistication, and discipline in
the budgetary process might recommend a different course.
c. Comment of
Commissioners Corzine
and Levy: These weaknesses in the budget process may have macro
as well as micro consequences. One of the aggregate effects of
sub-optimal choices may, at times, be either an inadequate or an
excessive level of capital spending.
d. Comment
of
Commissioners Corzine,
Leone, and O'Cleireacain: We believe it is both possible and
desirable to move toward classifying the federal budget in two
parts: as "capital," in the sense of investment with long-term
effects: and as "operating," such as consumption expenditures and
transfer payments for the current year. This approach, which is
consistent with private sector organizations' practices, would
enable the U.S. government to better understand, manage, and
finance its commitments.
As is the custom at the
state and local levels of government, a capital budget
classification does not mean that the government would lose its
flexibility to manage during periods of fiscal constraint/plenty.
Nor does it mean that all capital expenditures must be financed
from borrowed funds. Moreover, the definition of capital, like
other aspects of the current budget structure, could be refined
and updated over time.
e. Comment of
Commissioners Kramer,
Leone, and O'Cleireacain: We believe the text over-emphasizes "theoretical" market discipline
when it comes to borrowing for capital by the states. Most states, as a simple
matter of "capacity to pay," could borrow much more than they do. In
fact, almost always, in the real world the actual constraints are
political (including referendum requirements) and
practical--demands for current revenues limit the amounts
available for debt service.
f. Comment of
Commissioner Levy: I
urge the Congress to address the lease-purchase problem as part
of a special or comprehensive amendment to the current budget
process. I discuss this issue in greater detail in a subsequent
footnote (l).
g. Comment
of
Commissioners Lynn,
Penner, and Stein: We do not believe that this four-way
classification of expenditures would be helpful in making good
budgetary decisions.
h. Comment
of Commissioner Levy: A distinction must be made between practical and
theoretical definitions. Defining investment based on its benefits (such as
"increasing
social welfare" or "increasing long-term growth") is useful in theoretical discussions, but no
accounting is possible since we can never be sure which outlays qualify. At the same time,
practical definitions--such as those embodied in Generally Accepted Accounting Principles
(GAAP)--always have shortcomings, but still can be very useful. If we are to consider using
investment or capital in federal accounting and budgeting, then we must resign ourselves to the
use of practical definitions. The definitions of the Federal Accounting Standards Advisory Board
(FASAB) are a functioning example.
i. Comment of
Commissioner Stein: I believe the critical issue here is whether
the outlay rate is slower than the benefit rate--to the
decision-maker or to the country.
j. Comment of
Commissioner Levy: A multi-year outlay period for capital can at
best lessen the bias against capital spending, but I cannot see
how it could exert a bias in favor of capital spending, as seems
to be implied by the text. When the outlay caps are the binding
constraint, Congress may indeed "spend more than it otherwise would if budget authority were
binding. However, that does not imply that Congress would spend as much as
it would with a clear, long-term perspective. As long as the life
of the purchased capital is longer than the period over which its
purchase outlays are scored, then the scoring system is biased
against the purchase of such an asset. I have great difficulty
imagining many examples of government capital for which the
length of the outlay period is as long as--not to mention longer
than--the life of that capital.
k. Comment
of Commissioner Penner: I believe that a rule requiring the
capitalization of all short-term lease payments should be adopted
and that the estimation problems associated with such a rule are
no more severe than those encountered in estimating the cost of
many credit programs.
l. Comment
of Commissioner Levy: The scoring of leases versus purchases of
capital assets should be addressed by Congress, either in
isolation or as part of a comprehensive overhaul of the budget
process. For example, Congress might require any short-term lease
or building to be certified as the superior choice in the long
run. I agree with Commissioner Penner that short-term leases
should be capitalized for purposes of comparing them with the
cost of purchasing a capital asset, but I would like to emphasize
that a capitalized five-year lease cannot be compared with the
price of a building that will last at least 30 years. Analysts
should consider the cost of leasing over 30 years, or else
compare the options over five years with the estimated market
value of the purchased building added back at the end of five
years.
m. Comment
of Commissioners Lynn, Penner, and Stein: We do not believe that
this four-way classification of expenditures would be helpful in
making good budgetary decisions.
n. Comment
of Commissioner Levy: Although there are reasons to limit the
size of federal debt and deficits, I cannot agree that deficits divert
national saving away from other
uses. I and other economists argue that investment generally
determines saving, not the other way around. Certainly saving
equals investment is a fact,
an accounting identity. However, the notion that government
actions to increase or decrease public saving will similarly
increase or decrease investment is a theoretical proposition that
is neither universally accepted nor empirically proven. Notably,
it ignores the offsetting impact of changes in fiscal policy on
business saving (profits).
o. Comment
of
Commissioner Levy:
Under some types of a capital budget, there might be more gross
and net investment, which under a borrowing-for-investment rule,
would justify more borrowing.
ENDNOTES
1. This
should not be
surprising. One thoughtful economist writing in 1965 noted that "he
number of different definitions of "capital"' employed in the writings of
economists defy enumeration'' [Dewey, p. 4].
2. The
Bureau of
Economic Analysis,
which is responsible for the National Income and Product Accounts
(NIPA), has developed an experimental account for research and
development capital, however.
3. The outlays
shown
in the table
include the subsidy component of federal credit programs aimed at
supporting or stimulating capital spending.
4. It is
important in
reading Table 1 to bear in mind that the different categories of capital
spending may have very different economic (and non-economic)
effects. For example, it is highly likely that all, or close to
all, federal expenditures on defense capital and R&D createcapital that
would otherwise not exist. Some federal spending on non-defense
capital_such ashighways and other
capital grants to the states_may displace spending that would
otherwise occur at the state and local levels. Similarly, some
portion of the subsidies on student loans probably gets
translated into higher tuition rather than more education. At the
same time, it is also possible that federal matching grants for
infrastructure may encourage states and localities to invest more
than they otherwise would. In addition, it may be fairer or more
efficient for the federal government to finance certain
infrastructure than for local residents to bear all of the cost.
The key point is that different types of federal capital spending
have different impacts on the nation's overall stock of capital
(as do federal surpluses, deficits, and taxes).
5. The federal
tax code
contains a
variety of incentives designed to enhance various types of
capital spending, including (but not limited to): tax-exemption
of interest on state and local bonds used to finance
infrastructure and other physical investment; tax incentives for
private research and development expenditures; and various tax
incentives that support investment in education.
6. In the
National
Income and Product Accounts, depreciation is also deducted to determine the
federal government's "current surplus or deficit."
7. The GDP
data have
been adjusted for inflation using the chain-weighted GDP deflator, while
investment expenditures have been deflated using a chain-weighted
investment deflator.
8. Aschauer,
1989; see
also Munnell, 1992. The Boskin Commission report recently argued that the
inflation data are overstated for various reasons, which if true,
would also mean that real output and productivity are
understated. This report has been the subject of considerable controversy,
however, among economists.
9. For a
summary of
such studies, see Gramlich, 1994 and CBO, 1998.
10. There
are
differences in ownership of certain key sectors of the economy where investment
in physical assets is especially important. For example,
transportation and utility services that are publicly provided in
other countries are not provided by governments here (utility
services being a prime example, with the exception of some
federal hydroelectric projects and municipally owned power
companies). In addition, in countries where the government
provides hospital care services (such as the United Kingdom),
investments in hospitals show up as government capital spending,
whereas in the United States most health care is delivered
privately (with the exception of military and veterans' hospitals
and some municipally owned hospitals). Similarly, in the United
States, much higher education is provided privately, whereas in
many countries higher education is more likely to be provided
publicly. While these differences in ownership patterns between
countries do not affect comparisons of total national investment,
they do distort comparisons of capital spending by governments.
11.
The use of the word "capital"
in the financial accounting context can be confusing, since the
term is often interpreted as the shareholder's contribution to
the company, and not a category of assets, which is the way the
term is often defined by economists and government policy makers.
12. Under
GAAP,
capital assets are recorded, with some exceptions, at their original costs (minus any
cumulative depreciation in the case of fixed assets), and not at their current market
values.
13. There is
a GAAP
for state/local governments, and the body responsible for its principles is the
Governmental Accounting Standards Board (GASB).
14. For
mature firms
with access to credit, equity is typically the last means of financing (other
than through stock options to employees) because new equity
dilutes the ownership percentages of existing shareholders. For
new or young firms without a track record of profitability,
equity may be the only means of financing, whether by selling new
shares or granting stock options or shares to employees in lieu
of cash.
15. An
alternative way
of evaluating
capital projects that is sometimes used is to compute their
internal rates of return, or IRR, and to compare the result with
the discount rate.The IRR is
that discount
rate that theoretically equates the discounted future cash flows
to thecost of the
project or
that produces a zero NPV. If the IRR exceeds the discount rate,
thenproceeding
with the
project is justified. In practice, however, the IRR can be
difficult to computeand yields
different
results from NPV when cash flows are very uneven.
16. This
need not
always be the case,
however. Firms that manage their spending through something
analogous to the "statement of cash flow" in effect combine
their budgeting for operating expenses and capital items.
17. The
material in this
subsection
is drawn from National Association of State Budget Officers,
1997; OMB, 1998, p. 154; Hush and Peroff; and GAO, 1986.
18.
Typically, states
include in
their definitions of capital expenditures major maintenance,
although dollar thresholds for defining what maintenance is
``major'' also vary across states.
19. States
do record
depreciation
expense in their proprietary (or commercial-type) funds and in
trust funds where net income, expense, or capital maintenance is
measured.
20.
Examples of special
funds include
the Land and Water Conservation Fund and the National Wildlife
Refuge Fund.
21. Two
other types of
government
funds are ``public enterprise funds'' (revolving funds that
conduct business-type operations with the public) and
``intragovernmental funds'' (that do the same within and between
government agencies).
22. The
historical
material
summarized in this and the subsequent two paragraphs draws on
Nuzzo.
23. It
should be noted
that although
the budget does not distinguish between capital and operating
expenditures, the Analytical Perspectives volume of the
budget contains information that makes that distinction at an
aggregate level and for major programs.
24. The
Reagan
administration defined
investment primarily to cover defense expenditures. The Bush
administration broadened the term to include federal expenditures
on R&D, infrastructure, child immunization, drugs, the
environment and energy, and programs aimed at preserving
America's heritage (such as those for the arts, humanities, and
museums). The Clinton administration has used a similar
definition, but has concentrated on transportation, environment,
rural development, energy, community development and defense
conversion, housing, education, justice, health care, and
investments in information technology to improve the delivery of
government services.
25. For an
elaboration
of this point,
see Eichengreen, p. 84. Indeed, there is empirical evidence
indicating that state governments have been effectively rationed
out of the market when the ratio of their outstanding debt rises
above 9 percent of state economic output [Bayoumi, Goldstein, and
Woglom].
26. New
Zealand also
imposes a
``capital charge'' on each agency, which is paid to the Treasury
twice a year. Although the capital charges of the various
agencies are washed out on the overall government's budget, they
were adopted as a means of encouraging departments to manage
their capital assets wisely [Troup Testimony]. Below, we suggest
that the federal government experiment with a similar procedure,
the establishment of ``capital acquisition funds.''
27. The
Adequacy of
Appropriations
Act and the Antideficiency Act require allagencies to
have budget
authority for all obligations, including capital acquisitions.
28. The
``social'' rate of
return of
a project measures the benefit of the project to the nation as a
whole,
taking into account both economic and non-economic considerations
(such as equity and
freedom).
Social returns exceed the returns earned by the private sector
alone where the projects
generate
benefits beyond those reaped only by those who undertake them.
For example, it
is widely
acknowledged that much basic R&D undertaken by the government generates
benefits for
many firms and industries, as well as society as a whole. The
same is true for
education, which
confers benefits not just on the individuals who receive it, but
also on the entire
society to the
extent that a more educated work force is likely to come up with
new ideas that make
businesses
more productive.
29. As
former CBO
Director Robert
Reischauer pointed out in his testimony, the federal
government also
pays attention to distributional concerns: ``On the basis of
economic considerations alone,
the federal government would allocate far less to roads and
bridges and public
buildings in
North Dakota than it now does. But there is agreement that all
areas of the country
should enjoy the
advantages of a modern highway system, even where the economic payoff is
minimal.''
[Reischauer, p. 3].
30. The
FASAB
consists of nine
members: one representative each from OMB, Treasury,
GAO, and CBO;
two representatives from other executive branch agencies; and
three representatives from the
private sector or state and local government. FASAB has developed
two statements
of accounting
concepts and ten statements of standards applicable to accounting
by the federal
government.
31. The Act
significantly increased total funding for highways to $217
billion for FY1998-2003,
a substantial
increase over the $155 billion authorized for the preceding five
years. The
commission as a
whole takes no position on the merits of this funding level, but
notes only that the
linkage between
future spending and revenue dedicated to the trust fund addresses
the problem
that, in prior
years, motor fuels tax revenues were not being fully used for
their intended purpose.
32. Nor do
the
aggregate
investment and capital stock data currently reported in the Analytical
Perspectives and in the National Income and Product
Accounts reveal the physical condition of
those
assets (which are reported at current cost minus an adjustment
for accumulated
depreciation).
33. As Paul
Posner
from
the GAO told the commission: ``Prudent capital planning can help
agencies to make
the most of limited resources, while failure to make timely and
effective capital
acquisitions can
result in increased long-term costs'' [Posner at 14]. As an
example, Posner pointed to
planning
failures that have led to cost overruns, schedule delays, and
performance shortfalls in
the
Federal Aviation Administration's modernization program. Similar
problems appear to
have plagued
the computer modernization program at the Internal Revenue
Service. Inits recent
Capital
Programming Guide, OMB encourages agencies to develop
long-term capital plans
as part of
their planning process and to use these plans to develop their
annual budget
justifications.
34. Debt
service is an
appropriate rental charge whether or not the federal government
must borrow
to finance a certain project. In particular, even if the
government is running an
overall
surplus, there is an opportunity cost associated with the
acquisition of a capitalism--measured by the
cost of borrowing--associated with not having an even larger
surplus.
35. It would
not be
appropriate or useful to include in the CAFs grants to states or localities for
what, in
other contexts, may be deemed to be capital expenditures, such as
those for highways.
The grant
itself is the program; highways and other federally assisted
capital assets are not being
used to
provide federal services, so there are no federal programs to
which the cost of using this
capital
should be allocated for budget decision-making. Moreover,
spending ``spikes''tend to be
associated
with the construction or acquisition of federally owned
facilities; spending on highways
and other
``capital'' items tends to be relatively smooth from year to
year.
36. Some
agencies have
portions of their budgets considered by more than one appropriations
subcommittee. For example, while most of the budget of the
Department of the Interior is
considered
by the Interior subcommittee, the Energy and Water Development subcommittee has
jurisdiction specifically over the budget of the Bureau of
Reclamation (an agency
within Interior).
Similarly, the Labor/HHS subcommittee oversees most of the budget
of the
Department of Health
and Human Services, but the Agriculture subcommittee has
jurisdiction over the
budget of the
Food and Drug Administration. In these cases, it may be necessary
to establish
multiple CAFs
that fit jurisdictional boundaries of the appropriations
subcommittees.
37.
Moreover, a federal
mandate linking
federal funding to state and local support of maintenance
might
encourage rating agencies to allow bonding for maintenance.
38. The
number refers
to the section of the
BEA that provides for allocating spending totals within
the cap
among the appropriations subcommittees.
39. Note
that one virtue
of a CAF is that the
rental rate that would be charged implicitly on the use of capital
assets would
include a charge for depreciation.
40. The depreciation
total reported
by OMB and shown in the table includes depreciation of education
and R&D expenditures.
SELECTED REFERENCES
AND BIBLIOGRAPHY
Aschauer, David Alan. "Is Public Expenditure Productive?", Journal of Monetary
Economics, 1989, Vol. 23, pp. 177-200.
Bayoumi, Tamim; Morris Goldstein; and Geoffrey Woglom. "Do Credit Markets Discipline
Sovereign Borrowers? Evidence from U.S. States" (International Monetary Fund, Washington,
D.C., 1994).
Brown, Gordon. "Statement By The Chancellor of the Exchequor on the Economic and
Fiscal Strategy Report," House of Commons, June 11, 1998.
Congressional Budget Office. CBO papers: The Economic Effects of Federal
Spending on Infra-structure and Other Investments, June 1998.
Dewey, Donald, Modern Capital Theory (Columbia University Press, New
York, 1965).
Eichengreen, Barry. International Monetary Arrangements for the 21st Century
(The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., 1994).
General Accounting Office. Department of Energy: Opportunity to Improve
Management of Major System Acquisitions (GAO/RCED-97-17, November 26,
1996).
______________________. The Role of Depreciation in Budgeting for Certain
Federal Investments (GAO/AIMB-95-34, February 1995).
______________________. Budget Issues: Incorporating an Investment Component
in the Budget. (GAO/AIMD-94-40, November 1993).
______________________. Budget Issues: Capital Budgeting Practices in the
States. (GAO/AFMD-86-63FS, July 1986).
Gramlich, Edward M. "Infrastructure Investment: A Review Essay," Journal of
Economic Literature. September 1994, Vol. 32, No. 3, pp. 1176-1196.
Hush, Lawrence W., and Kathleen Peroff. "The Variety of State Capital Budgets: A Survey,"
Public Budgeting and Finance. Vol. 8, Summer 1988.
Kirova, Milka S., and Robert E. Lipsey. "Measuring Real Investment: Trends in the United
States and International Comparison," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review. January/February 1998, 3-18.
Munnell, Alicia H. "Infrastructure Investment and Investment Growth," Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Fall 1992, Vol. 6, No. 4, pp. 189-98.
National Association of State Budget Officers. Capital Budgeting in the States
(September 1997).
Nuzzo, James L.J. "Whither a Federal Capital Budget." (Harvard Law School, unpublished
manuscript, May 1994).
Office of Management and Budget. Analytical Perspectives, FY 1999 Budget
(February 1998).
____________________________ and Chief Financial Officers Council. Federal
Financial Management Status Report & Five Year Plan (June 1998).
Posner, Paul L. "Budgeting for Capital," Testimony before the Commission. March 6,
1998.
Reischauer, Robert. Testimony before the Commission. April 24, 1998.
Schick, Allen. The Federal Budget Process: Politics, Policy, Process.
(Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1995).
Tillet, Ronald L. "Capital Planning and Budgeting in the Commonwealth of Virginia."
Presentation to the Commission. May 8, 1998.
Troup, George. "Capital Budgeting in the New Zealand Government." Testimony before the
Commission. May 8, 1998.
APPENDIX A
Executive Order 13037:
Commission to Study Capital Budgeting, and the Amendments
Federal Register
Presidential Documents
Vol. 62, No. 44 Thursday, March 6, 1997
Executive Order 13037 of March 3, 1997
Commission To Study
Capital Budgeting
By the authority vested in me as President by
the Constitution and the laws of the United States of America,
including the Federal Advisory Committee Act, as amended (5
U.S.C. App.), it is hereby ordered as follows:
Section 1. Establishment.
There
is established the Commission to Study Capital Budgeting
("Commission"). The
Commission shall be bipartisan and shall be
composed of 11 members appointed by the President. The members of
the Commission shall be chosen from among individuals with
expertise in public and private finance, government officials,
and leaders in the labor and business communities. The President
shall designate two co-chairs from among the members of the
Commission.
Sec. 2. Functions.The
Commission shall report on the following:
(a) Capital budgeting practices in other
countries, in State and local governments in this country, and in
the private sector; the differences and similarities in their
capital budgeting concepts and processes; and the pertinence of
their capital budgeting practices for budget decisionmaking and
accounting for actual budget outcomes by the Federal Government;
(b) The appropriate definition of capital for
Federal budgeting, including: use of capital for the Federal
Government itself or the economy at large; ownership by the
Federal Government or some other entity; defense and nondefense
capital; physical capital and intangible or human capital;
distinctions among investments in and for current, future, and
retired workers; distinctions between capital to increase
productivity and capital to enhance the quality of life; and
existing definitions of capital for budgeting;
(c) The role of depreciation in capital
budgeting, and the concept and measurement of depreciation for
purposes of a Federal capital budget; and
(d) The effect of a Federal capital budget on
budgetary choices between capital and noncapital means of
achieving public objectives; implications for macroeconomic
stability; and potential mechanisms for budgetary discipline.
Sec. 3. Report.The
Commission shall adopt its report through majority vote of its
full membership. The Commission shall report to the National
Economic Council by March 15, 1998, or within 1 year from its
first meeting.
Sec. 4. Administration.
(a)
Members of the Commission shall serve without compensation for
their work on the Commission. While engaged in the work of the
Commission, members appointed from among private citizens of the
United States may be allowed travel expenses, including per diem
in lieu of subsistence, as authorized by law for persons serving
intermittently in the Government service (5 U.S.C. 5701095707).
(b) The Department of the Treasury shall
provide the Commission with funding and administrative support.
The Commission may have a paid staff, including detailees from
Federal agencies. The Secretary of the Treasury shall perform the
functions of the President under the Federal Advisory Committee
Act, as amended (5 U.S.C. App.), except that of reporting to the
Congress, in accordance with the guidelines and procedures
established by the Administrator of General Services.
Sec. 5. General Provisions.
The
Commission shall terminate 30 days after submitting its report.
William J. Clinton
THE WHITE HOUSE,
March 3, 1997
Federal Register
Presidential Documents
Vol. 62, No. 211 Friday, October 31, 1997
Executive Order 13066 of October 29,
1997
Amendment to Executive
Order 13037, Commission To Study Capital Budgeting
By the authority vested in me as President by
the Constitution and the laws of the United States of America,
and in order to increase the membership of the Commission to
Study Capital Budgeting, it is hereby ordered that the second
sentence of section 1 of Executive Order 13037 is amended by
deleting "11" and inserting "no more than 20" in lieu thereof. It is further ordered that section 3
of Executive Order 13037 is amended by deleting the words "by
March 15, 1998, or".
William J. Clinton
THE WHITE HOUSE
October 29, 1997
Federal Register
Presidential Documents
Vol. 63, No. 240 Tuesday, December 15, 1998
Executive Order 13108 of December 11,
1998
Further Amendment to
Executive Order 13037, Commission To Study Capital Budgeting
By the authority vested in me as President by
the Constitution and the laws of the United States of America,
and in order to extend the reporting deadline for, and the
expiration date of, the Commission to Study Capital Budgeting, it
is hereby ordered that Executive Order 13037, as amended, is
further amended by deleting in section 3 of that order "within
1 year from its first meeting" and inserting in lieu thereof "by February
1, 1999" and by deleting in section 5 of that order "30
days after submitting its report" and inserting in lieu thereof "on September
30, 1999".
William J. Clinton
THE WHITE HOUSE
December 11, 1998
APPENDIX B
Commission Membership
Co-Chairs
Kathleen Brown is President of Bank of America's Private Bank
West. She has been with Bank of America since 1994. From 1991 until 1994,
she served as California's 28th Treasurer, responsible for managing the
state's investment portfolio, and administering bond sales to finance schools,
parks, prisons, housing, health facilities, and environmental programs.
Ms. Brown was the Democratic nominee for Governor of California in 1994.
Jon S. Corzine is Co-Chairman and Senior Partner of the investment
banking firm Goldman, Sachs & Co. Since joining the firm in 1975, he
has held a variety of positions including partner-in-charge of government,
mortgage and money markets trading, co-head of the Fixed Income Division
and of the firm's treasury and finance functions, and Chief Executive Officer.
Members
Willard W. Brittain, of New York, New York, is Global Managing
Partner of PricewaterhouseCoopers.
Stanley E. Collender, of Washington, D.C., is a Senior Vice President
and Managing Director of the Federal Budget Consulting Group at Fleishman-Hillard.
Orin S. Kramer, of Englewood, New Jersey, is a general partner
of Kramer Spellman, L.P., which manages investment vehicles focusing on
the financial services industry.
Richard C. Leone, of Princeton, New Jersey, is the President
of The Century Foundation, formerly the Twentieth Century Fund, Inc., a
public policy research institution in New York. He was New Jersey State
Treasurer and Chief Financial and Budget Officer for 1973-1977.
David Levy, of Pound Ridge, New York, is the Vice Chairman of
the Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College and Director of the
Levy Institute Forecasting Center.
James T. Lynn, of Bethesda, Maryland, is retired Chairman and
Chief Executive Officer of Aetna Life& Casualty. During the Ford Administration,
he served as Director of the Office of Management and Budget.
Cynthia A. Metzler, of Washington DC, is a Partner with the law
firm of Pepper Hamilton LLP. She was formerly Acting Secretary of Labor
during the Clinton Administration.
Luis Nogales, of Beverly Hills, California, is President of Nogales
Partners, and was Chairman and CEO of Embarcadero Media and United Press
International and President of Univision.
Carol O'Cleireacain, of New York, New York, is a Senior Fellow
at The Brookings Institution and former Finance Commissioner and Budget
Director of New York City.
Rudolph G. Penner, of Washington, D.C., holds the Arjay and Frances
Miller Chair in Public Policy at the Urban Institute. He is a former Director
of the Congressional Budget Office.
Steven L. Rattner, of New York, New York, is Deputy Chief Executive
of the investment banking firm Lazard Freres & Co. LLC.
Robert M. Rubin, of Southampton, New York, is Executive Vice
President and Director of AIG Trading Group, an international currency
and commodity dealer.
Herbert Stein, of Washington, D.C., is a senior fellow of the
American Enterprise Institute. He served as Chairman of the Council of
Economic Advisers under Presidents Nixon and Ford.